Program Implementation & Evaluation - Political Science
The four readings issues associated with how to study the implementation of public policies or programs:
The relationship of politics to public policy?
Whether and how to address cooperation usually between or among different government agencies or departments?
Uncertainty (what we know and don’t know)?
Bias associated with evaluating public policies or programs. discuss these four parts that make up the study of implementation? show how they are inter-related.
Help discuss the readings as part minimum of six pages
When Does Cooperation Improve Public
Policy Implementation?
Martin Lundin
Interorganizational cooperation is often considered valuable in the public sector. However, in this
article it is suggested that the impact of cooperation on public policy implementation is dependent on
the type of policy being carried out. It is argued that complex policies are more effectively put into
practice if agencies cooperate a lot, whereas less difficult tasks are handled just as well without
interorganizational cooperation. Thus, two policies within the Swedish active labor market policy are
examined. The empirical test focuses on the cooperation between Public Employment Service offices
and municipal labor market administrations. In agreement with the hypothesis, the findings suggest
that policy matters. The implementation of one of the policies—the complex policy—is enhanced if
cooperation between agencies increase. On the other hand, cooperation does not improve implementa-
tion of the less complex task. The study is based on quantitative data.
KEY WORDS: implementation, interorganizational cooperation, policy, active labor market policy,
Sweden
Relationships between authorities impinge on policy implementation (O’Toole,
2003) and it is often emphasized that public policy can be carried out better if
cooperation increases among agencies. Some scholars claim that interorganizational
cooperation is inherently good (e.g., Hudson, Hardy, Henwood, & Wistow, 1999;
Jones, Thomas, & Rudd, 2004), although empirical evidence suggests that coopera-
tion only sometimes enhances performance (Jennings & Ewalt, 1998). The purpose of
this article is to enrich our understanding of policy implementation by examining
when a cooperative strategy actually makes implementation output better. More
precisely, it is argued that the effects of cooperation vary with the complexity of the
policy carried out.
An agency that cooperates with others can make use of additional resources,
such as expertise and information. Activities can hopefully also be better co-
ordinated. This suggests that interorganizational cooperation improves an agency’s
ability to put policy into practice. On the other hand, it is difficult to work across
organizational boundaries. For example, the collaborating authorities have to devote
a lot of time and other resources to establishing and maintaining a productive
relationship. Thus, we cannot be sure that cooperation improves implementation in
The Policy Studies Journal, Vol. 35, No. 4, 2007
629
0190-292X © 2007 The Policy Studies Journal
Published by Blackwell Publishing. Inc., 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ.
every situation. In this article, it is suggested that task complexity is a key factor that
explains why the effect of cooperation on implementation output will be greater in
certain situations. Basically, the benefits of cooperation are likely to more than offset
the costs if the task is complex. In contrast, when the policy is not complex co-
operation adds very little value, but still involves some costs. To my knowledge, this
idea has previously not been thoroughly discussed and empirically evaluated in
implementation research.
The empirical focus is relations between different units of government. More
precisely, the analysis concerns Public Employment Service (PES) offices and their
relationship to local governments (municipalities) in the Swedish active labor market
policy (ALMP). The PES is the main local labor market actor. But in recent years,
municipalities have become an increasingly important factor (Lundin & Skedinger,
2006; Salonen & Ulmestig, 2004). The Swedish government encourages cooperation
between these actors. But will implementation of labor market activities actually be
improved if the PES cooperates a lot with the municipality? Is it possible to anticipate
a positive effect on a broad range of policies, or is it only certain labor market
activities that are affected positively?
Two policies are examined. One of the policies—activities for unemployed
youth—is not that complex. The other—activities for individuals with especially long
spells of unemployment—is more intricate. Thus, I expect cooperation to be a more
efficient strategy in the latter case. The quantitative analysis is based on recent data
consisting of information from several sources. The findings indicate that coopera-
tion improves the implementation of activities for individuals unemployed for an
especially long time. On the other hand, cooperation does not enhance the imple-
mentation of the youth policy. This indicates that complex tasks can be carried out
better if a cooperative approach is employed, but that it is not reasonable to assume
that interorganizational cooperation will always have a positive impact on how
policies are implemented.
The rest of the article is structured as follows. First, the theoretical discourse is
outlined. An introduction of the research setting comes next, followed by a section
that discusses methodological issues and measures. Empirical findings are reported.
I conclude by summing up the results and discussing their possible implications.
Implementation and Interorganizational Cooperation
Local practices are not always the same as the intentions stated in official docu-
ments endorsed by politicians. In addition, performance frequently varies from one
local context to another. As a result, it is wise not to assume that the study of statutes,
government bills, and regulations will be enough to understand what political deci-
sions imply “in the real world.”1
An implementation problem occurs when a political decision is not carried out
in accordance with what the decision maker wants. We assume that local practice
should be in line with the elected officials’ intentions, that is, agents should follow
the principal’s instructions. This perspective is easy to endorse, based on normative
democratic theory. In a modern democracy, citizens freely elect representatives who
630 Policy Studies Journal, 35:4
can be held to account at the ballot box. Politicians cannot implement a policy all by
themselves; they have to rely on a civil service to do this. But the citizens cannot
replace the bureaucracy by casting their vote. Consequently, a prerequisite for satis-
factory democracy is that politicians control and govern a civil service that respects
their decisions (Sannerstedt, 2001).
There are arguments in favor of another point of view, which argues that the
local civil service is more receptive to local desires and needs. Discrepancies between
a decision and its implementation might therefore in practice mean a “better” policy
and a greater responsiveness to citizens’ wishes. Depending on which normative
starting point is assumed, variation in—or insufficient—implementation perfor-
mance is thus not always necessarily a disadvantage (deLeon, 1999). Nonetheless,
most scholars would concur that it is troublesome if there is a gap between the law
and practice (Keiser & Soss, 1998). In this article, I focus on the top-down aspect of
implementation, that is, implementation as compliance. It is, however, necessary to
acknowledge that other angles of approach are just as relevant in implementation
research.
Certain political decisions are quite easy to carry out and can be managed almost
exclusively by a unitary public administration. A change in a tax rate or the level
of a general welfare benefit is virtually self-implemented. But implementation is
normally more complicated and involves several participants. Hence, an important
component in almost every contemporary framework explaining implementation
success and failure has to do with how interorganizational relationships are
managed (e.g., Bardach, 1998; Goggin, Bowman, Lester, & O’Toole, 1990; Hjern &
Porter, 1981; O’Toole, 2003; O’Toole & Montjoy, 1984; Pressman & Wildavsky, 1984;
Winter, 2003a).
An agency assigned the task of carrying out a political decision may use different
techniques to implement a policy. For instance, the agency may try to cooperate as
much as possible with other organizations. Cooperation (collaboration)—that is, all
the interactions among organizations aimed at solving public problems by working
together (cf. Smith, Carroll, & Ashford, 1995)—is one of the golden words in public-
sector management. Through partnerships and other collaborative endeavors, public-
sector performance is often considered to be improved. All else being equal, one
would expect a public agency with access to significant resources to carry out a policy
or program better than an agency which lacks resources (e.g., Keiser & Soss, 1998;
Meier & McFarlane, 1996). Organizations possess resources. An agency carrying out a
political decision may thus enhance its own capacity by collaborating with other
organizations (e.g., Jennings, 1994). The surrounding organizations may contribute
with information, and they could have staff, knowledge, money, and premises,
making the business of putting ideas into practice easier. Cooperation can also mean
that resource-consuming and conflicting activities that may result in socially perverse
outcomes are avoided (Hooghe & Marks, 2003). Thus, it is easy to see why inter-
organizational cooperation is often assumed to improve implementation.
But there are a number of prerequisites. First, the potential partner must have
additional resources that can be of use to the focal agency. Second, the partner
must be willing to share resources. Third, there are always costs associated with
Lundin: Cooperation and Public Policy Implementation 631
collaboration (e.g., Schermerhorn, 1975; Van de Ven, 1976; Weiss, 1987). Although a
potential partner is willing to share valuable resources with the focal agency, coop-
eration may be a complicated process. To at least some extent, all organizations have
different agendas and various routines to handle things. As a consequence, interor-
ganizational cooperation may be a complicated process involving bargaining, and
therefore call for considerable time and other resources on the part of the agents
concerned. Another cost to be considered is that the principal’s objectives—for
example, central government intentions—may be put on one side when the local
agents concerned are trying to reach their best joint solution. In other words, instead
of pursuing central government directives, local actors may work for other goals
they can agree on. In sum, the costs of cooperating might well outweigh the benefits
and we should not assume that more cooperation implies that political intentions are
always realized to a greater extent.
Cooperation can, of course, have important implications for other aspects than
implementation output. For instance, a public program might become more effective
if authorities cooperate, even if implementation is not enhanced.2 Cooperation might
also imply that a decision becomes more legitimate in the eyes of the target group for
a certain policy. But this study is limited to the question of how to make a political
decision come true in accordance with officials’ intentions.
Jennings and Ewalt (1998) note that there is only anecdotal evidence that
coordination—which in practice is measured as the level of cooperation—actually
improves public services. Jennings and Ewalt examine the accomplishment of policy
goals in employment and training services in the United States. In a prior article,
Jennings (1994) indicated positive effects of coordination on the administrators’
subjective perceptions of performance. But in the study from 1998, objective
outcome measures were employed as dependent variables. The analysis shows that
coordination has a limited positive effect; most of the indicators were unaffected by
the level of coordination. The findings suggest that although interorganizational
cooperation may sometimes be a good strategy, we cannot expect it always to
improve performance. There is some indication that there is a positive effect in the
long run, but the evidence is not decisive. On the other hand, Hudson et al. (1999, p.
238) note that “while recognizing that there are other positions, this article takes the
normative position that collaboration is generally a ‘good thing’—a stance which is
consistent with the rather long history of collaboration in organization theory and
public administration.” In many ways this is certainly true, but if we want to under-
stand public administration and public policy implementation it must be better to
improve theory on what the balance of benefits and costs would look like in various
situations. This can tell us when cooperation actually is a good strategy.
There seems to be a lack of research on these matters. Pressman and Wildavsky
(1984) suggest that the number of actors involved in an interorganizational setting
determines whether implementation will be successful; more actors mean greater
probability of failure. O’Toole and Montjoy (1984) refine this argument and hold that
a large number of actors makes implementation worse in cases of reciprocal inter-
dependence (when actors poses contingencies for each other) and in sequential
interdependence (when the output of one actor is the input of another). Contrarily,
632 Policy Studies Journal, 35:4
in cases of pooled interdependence (when actors contribute to a task without dealing
with each other) and in sequential competitive interdependence (when there are
actors competing to do the same thing in the implementation process) a larger
number of actors improves policy output. These scholars focus on the effects of the
organizational setting per se, not the extent to which actors work together, which is
the focus in this article. The question here is rather whether a lot of cooperation
generates a better payoff, given certain tasks. More specifically, is a high degree of
cooperation especially rewarding for certain policy types?
The discussion is restricted to one policy dimension that deserves particular
attention: task complexity. Task complexity is defined as the product of the scope of
actions and the intensity required to carry out a policy. By scope I mean the extent to
which many areas of expertise are required to fulfill the goals or, put another way,
“the degree to which tasks are variable and require a multidisciplinary or multidi-
mensional approach” (Alter & Hage, 1993, p. 117). Intensity is a matter of how much
work has to be done in order to realize ambitions; a task that requires many man-
hours on the part of an agency is considered intense. A possible objection is that
complexity is only about the scope. However, I think that we should consider
intensity as well because the problems that a policy which has a great scope implies
are multiplied if intense actions also are required. Thus, in this article a policy that
has large scope and involves intense actions is considered complex. In research on
interfirm partnerships, it is quite common to talk about joint task complexity as a
function of the scope and depth (intensity) of interactions between firms (White,
2005). This definition parallels the one used in the present study. Most organization
theory scholars define complexity in a related vein, although there are alternatives on
the same theme (see, e.g., Alter & Hage, 1993, pp. 116–22).
Task complexity is an incentive for cooperation (cf. Alter & Hage, 1993). A need
for external resources boosts interorganizational cooperation (e.g., Van de Ven &
Walker, 1984; Weiss, 1987) and complex tasks may demand resources that cannot be
found within a single agency. In this perspective, actors cooperate when cooperation
is needed, otherwise they do not. But the extent of cooperation between two agen-
cies, A and B, is certainly not only a direct function of the task complexity of policy
X that A implements. Cooperation is a consequence of the agencies’ perceived total
value of working together, which may be something rather different from the actual
value that cooperation adds to the task of realizing policy X in accordance with
official intentions. First, the agencies do not have perfect information and cannot
take in all benefits and costs of cooperation: A does not know exactly what greater
value cooperation actually implies. Second, A cannot set cooperation precisely at the
optimal level on its own. If B does not want cooperation to increase, A cannot do
much about this. Third, the incentives and disincentives for A to cooperate with B are
numerous.3 External pressure for cooperation is one example. Political representa-
tives or other bureaucratic levels may exhort A to collaborate with B. In some cases,
a legal mandate may require A to cooperate with B. Norms and values in both
organizations are other things that determine cooperation. Moreover, working
together with B can make it easier for A to accomplish other goals than those related
to policy X. Accordingly, although the net benefit of cooperation for A can be
Lundin: Cooperation and Public Policy Implementation 633
positive, this does not mean that policy X becomes better implemented. In sum, it is
too restrictive to assume that task complexity impinges only on cooperation levels.
It can also tell us something about the effect on policy output. Whereas the other
factors mentioned above affect cooperation, it is only the cost–benefit analysis related
to the policy being implemented that determines the effect on implementation in the
specific case.
So the question is now why we should assume that the effect of cooperation
would be greater as policy complexity increases. In a less complex policy, it is likely
that the benefits of cooperation would be quite low. In these situations, the agency’s
capacity is not going to increase that much by using other organizations’ resources
because the most important resources are already available within the agency.
Organizations are formed to perform certain tasks and in a less complex policy the
most important resources are already available. This means that increasing levels of
cooperation do not add that much value. As complexity rises, cooperation provides
more benefits. The agency needs more expertise, information, money, premises, and
so on. Through cooperation these resources can be attained.
The costs must also be considered. As complexity increases, the costs of coop-
eration are also likely to increase. For instance, the risk of disputes and impediments
becomes greater. But while the benefits of cooperation are very low given little
complexity, there will always be costs. In fact, many costs are independent of the level
of complexity. Cooperation is a dynamic process and decisions and activities within
a policy are not independent of each other. Given that actors agree on some basic
things, the additional problems that arise with increasing complexity will not be that
high. In another context—interfirm alliances—White (2005) considers the costs asso-
ciated with cooperation. Even though he claims that costs are higher given a complex
task, he repeatedly notes that the benefits are often likely to be even greater. He
claims that “additional costs of a more complex interface may be more than offset by
the benefits possible from more extensive interaction” (p. 1388) and if the partners
have relatively similar objectives and values, “the additional marginal cooperation
costs resulting from greater scope or depth-related coordination costs should be
more than offset by increased benefits” (p. 1395).
In sum, it seems likely that in a situation characterized by low task complexity
there will be very little (or no) benefit from cooperation, but some costs. These costs
increase somewhat as complexity increases, but the increase will be lower than the
increase in benefits. If complexity is high, the large benefits will prevail over the
costs. Cooperation is therefore a more value-adding activity given complex tasks.
Accordingly, we should expect the effect of cooperation on policy output to be
greater given complex tasks. These arguments are perhaps not brand new, but to my
knowledge they have not been discussed and evaluated empirically in the context of
local policy implementation.
Intergovernmental Cooperation in Swedish Active Labor Market Policy
To discern whether complexity is an important variable, we need to know the
effects of cooperation on the implementation of at least two policies: one complex
634 Policy Studies Journal, 35:4
task and another less complex task. Swedish ALMP provides rather good opportu-
nities to examine this. Unemployment is a huge problem in most OECD countries
(Martin & Grubb, 2001). Job brokering activities and labor market programs are
examples of ALMPs a government can use to reduce these problems. In Sweden, the
National Labor Market Administration (Arbetsmarknadsverket) implements ALMPs.
Local PES offices (Arbetsförmedlingar) carry out most of the programs in practice.
There is a PES in nearly all cities, and in larger cities there is usually more than one
office.
Although the National Labor Market Administration is clearly the most impor-
tant authority managing ALMPs in Sweden, other actors are involved. One feature in
recent years has been more involvement on the part of local governments in the
implementation of ALMPs (e.g., Lundin, 2007; Lundin & Skedinger, 2006; Salonen &
Ulmestig, 2004). The municipalities take an active part by, for example, organizing
labor market programs. About 40 percent of the clients involved in programs admin-
istered by the National Labor Market Administration are participating in activities in
which the municipalities are involved (Lundin & Skedinger, 2006). A lot of the
municipal activities are targeted at social welfare benefit recipients (Salonen &
Ulmestig, 2004) and at unemployed youth (Carling & Larsson, 2005). The content of
the activities varies, but job-search assistance and work practice are quite common.
The municipalities have a premier position within the Swedish political system.
For example, they have the constitutional right of self-government; they are
comparably large; they can decide on their own organization; and their incomes
come mostly from a proportional income tax they can set freely (see, e.g., Bäck, 2003;
Gustafsson, 1999). The municipalities provide most of the services of the Swedish
welfare state. For instance, they supply day care, care of the elderly, social welfare
services, introduction of immigrants into Swedish society, and primary education.
Several of these policy areas—the most obvious example being social welfare
services—clearly intertwine with ALMPs. This suggests that collaboration with the
municipality could be beneficial for the PES.
In the analysis, effects of cooperation between the PES and the municipality on
implementation of ALMPs are studied. The study concerns two policies. One of the
policies is more complex. The positive effect of cooperation is anticipated to be
greater in this policy.
In August 2000, the Swedish government launched a new labor market program
called the Activity Guarantee (Aktivitetsgarantin). The target group was individuals
who had been unemployed for a considerable time period. By means of intense
job-search assistance and close monitoring, persons who were, or who risked being,
long-term unemployed were to be given a place in the program. All traditional
ALMPs could be used within the Activity Guarantee. Accordingly, the content of the
activities varies to a large extent. The political ambition was that jobseekers should be
enrolled in the program after 27 months of unbroken PES registration, at the latest.
What distinguishes the Activity Guarantee from other labor market programs is its
intensity. All activities are assumed to be full-time activities and the participants
should meet their personal PES supervisor on a regular basis, and more frequently
than before they entered the program. Since the persons participating in the
Lundin: Cooperation and Public Policy Implementation 635
guarantee are “hard cases” and often have multiple problems, the government calls
for intense treatment and encourages PES offices to collaborate with other local
actors. The local governments are, in practice, the PES offices’ most common coop-
eration partners (Forslund, Fröberg, & Lindqvist, 2004).
In 1994, the Swedish government declared that no young person should remain
unemployed for more than 100 days. The government regarded long-term unem-
ployment as devastating for future labor market prospects. Young people are defined
as long-term unemployed if they are unemployed for more than 100 days. Thus, the
ambition was that every individual of below 25 years of age should be offered a labor
market program if they were unable to find a job within three months of registration
at the local PES. The central government encouraged the municipalities to take part
in actions to reduce long-term unemployment among young people in different
ways. For instance, in 1995 the government introduced the Municipal Youth Program
(Kommunala ungdomsprogrammet) and three years later the UVG-guarantee (Ung-
domsgarantin). The PES offices are expected to collaborate with local governments in
both programs (Carling & Larsson, 2005).
Recall that task complexity is defined in terms of the scope and intensity of a
policy. The Activity Guarantee is more intense and has greater scope than the youth
policy. Thus, it is a good representative of a complex policy (and this applies even if
complexity is defined only in terms of the scope). First, consider the client groups. In
the Activity Guarantee, the clients are comparatively old and they are obviously not
particularly attractive on the labor market because they have been looking for a job
for such a long time. It is also reasonable to assume that a relatively large part of the
clients have multiple problems because the program is directed at those with the
weakest position on the labor market. In comparison, youth clients have not been
unemployed for such a long time. Consequently, they are probably more motivated,
more homogenous, and easier to handle. Accordingly, the treatment of clients in the
Activity Guarantee needs more areas of expertise and more intense activities.
Second, although various youth activities are probably not so simple to imple-
ment, the Activity Guarantee is more complex. The activities are supposed to be
rigorous and carried out in small groups. Contacts between clients and personal
supervisor are also expected to be more frequent than is generally the case. In short,
these activities are more intense. Moreover, the government’s intention was that the
program should be flexible and contain various activities suited for the individual
client. This means that the Activity Guarantee is intended to have greater scope than
other ALMPs. On balance, it is safe to conclude that the Activity Guarantee is much
more complex than the youth policy, even though some youth activities can also be
said to contain complexities. Thus, I predict a greater effect of cooperation on imple-
mentation output in the Activity Guarantee.
The selected research setting is suitable for several reasons. First, unemployment
is a large societal problem and a lot of resources are allocated to diminishing the
unemployment rate all around world. Studies that can bring some clarity to what is
going on when ALMPs are put into practice are therefore important. Second, this
study is focused on the relationships between the same types of actors who imple-
ment the same policies around Sweden. This implies that features of the agencies and
636 Policy Studies Journal, 35:4
the policies that do not vary can be held constant. From a methodological point of
view this is very beneficial. Third, Swedish ALMPs can be seen as a “critical case,”
meaning that here, if anywhere, we ought to expect that cooperation will improve
implementation on a broad range of activities. O’Toole (1983) claims that there are
very high information and expertise requirements in ALMPs. Interorganizational
cooperation is therefore likely to be a good strategy for gathering the necessary
resources. Furthermore, there are obvious connections between the responsibilities
of the PES offices and the municipalities. This means that we have good reasons for
believing that cooperation is a good strategy when it comes to both policies.
Method and Measures
Whereas quantitative approaches have become increasingly common and more
sophisticated in the implementation literature from the United States (e.g., Brehm &
Gates, 1997; Daley & Layton, 2004; Meier & McFarlane, 1996), studies based on
large-N data in the European context are rare. This study is based on European
quantitative data and is therefore a significant contribution.4 The PES offices are the
unit of analysis and cross-section data covering 2003 is used. Questionnaires were
distributed to the chief managers of all PES offices in February 2004: 268 managers
answered the questionnaire, which implies a response rate of 75 percent. An analysis
of the nonresponses showed no noticeable difference between respondents and
nonrespondents on background characteristics. Register data from the National
Labor Market Administration supplement the survey. Lastly, official statistics, in …
The Policy Studies Journal, Vol. 33, No. 4, 2005
0162-895X © 2005 The Policy Studies Journal
Published by Blackwell Publishing. Inc., 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ.
559
Facts and Myths about Research on Public Policy
Implementation: Out-of-Fashion, Allegedly Dead, But
Still Very Much Alive and Relevant
Harald Saetren
Despite several decades of research on public policy implementation we know surprisingly little, not
only about cumulative research results, but also about several other key aspects of this research field.
This article tries to amend these deficiencies by presenting the results of a comprehensive literature
survey. Its main purpose is to challenge, revise, and supplement some conventional wisdom about
implementation research. A second motivation is to lay the foundation for and initiate a much needed
synthesis of empirical research results. The main results are: The overall volume of publications on
policy implementation has not stagnated or declined dramatically since the mid 1980s as is commonly
asserted. On the contrary, it has continued to grow exponentially through the 1990s and into the
twenty-first century. Even more surprising is that a large number of publications are located outside
the core fields. Hence, the literature is substantially larger and more multidisciplinary than most com-
mentators realize. Doctoral dissertations are the most ignored, but probably the richest, largest, and
best source of empirical research results. Tracing the origin as well as the location of the disciplinary
and geographical cradle of implementation studies must also be readjusted significantly. The ethno-
centric bias of this research field toward the Western hemisphere has been, and still is, strong and some
policy sectors are given much more attention than others. Although positive in many ways, the pre-
dominant multidisciplinary character of implementation research still poses some serious problems
with respect to theory development. Thus, I discuss whether a resurgence of interest in policy imple-
mentation among policy scholars may already be occurring. Finally, I suggest that the time is long
overdue for efforts to synthesize research results in a more rigorous scientific manner than has hith-
erto been done.
KEY WORDS: public policy implementation, bibliometric survey, origin, size, development, discipli-
nary structure, relevance, research agenda
Introduction
Science must begin with myths and with the criticism of myths.
—Karl Popper
As a new field of investigation continues to grow and expand over several
decades, it becomes important to take stock of what has happened and what has
been achieved. If not, the knowledge and insights gained will become increasingly
560 Policy Studies Journal, 33:4
fragmented and inaccessible (Cooper & Hedges, 1994; Hunt, 1997). Quite a few
state-of-the-art reviews on public policy implementation research have been pub-
lished over the years (Alexander, 1985; Barrett, 2004; Goggin et al., 1990; Hill, 1997;
Hill & Hupe, 2002; Ingram, 1990; deLeon, 1999a; deLeon & deLeon, 2002; Lester &
Goggin, 1998; Lester et al., 1987; Linder & Peters, 1987; McLaughlin, 1987; Matland,
1995; May, 2003; O’Toole, 1986; 2000; 2004; Palumbo & Calista, 1990; Ryan, 1996;
Sabatier, 1986; Schofield, 2001, Schofield & Sausman, 2004; Sinclair, 2001; Winter,
1990; Winter, 2003; Yin, 1982). They have all, in their time, pointed to important
contributions and shortcomings in implementation research and offered valuable
advice with respect to improvements.
Nevertheless, surprisingly little is known about several key features of this type
of research which will be explicated further below. Another related problem is that
most reviewers fail to explain how they arrive at their many factual statements and
interpretations. This is not uncommon among review articles in social sciences
according to Jackson (1980, 444), but it precludes judgments regarding validity of
their assertions and conclusions. For the few exceptions, see O’Toole (1986), Hill and
Hupe (2002), and Sinclair (2001).
As a result, a certain story about implementation research—its origin, discipli-
nary foundation and development pattern, and so forth—has been retold so often
that it has now become institutionalized in the form of conventional wisdom. The
story has acquired this stature because it has never been challenged. Some key ele-
ments of this conventional wisdom were created by Pressman and Wildavsky (1973),
the presumed founding fathers of this type of research, at a time when it was much
more difficult to keep track of research publications and their contents. These found-
ing fathers made their claims in good faith. However, given the superior research
tools and data resources at hand today, there is now little excuse when one uncrit-
ically perpetuates that dubious account. It is time to set the record straight!
What parts of the institutionalized story about implementation research are
correct and which are not? The story is also incomplete in certain respects. That is,
there are some important aspects of this research to which nobody has claimed
knowledge. The primary aim of this article is to provide a more complete, factual
account about implementation research at the outset of the new millennium. This
entails recounting its origin, evolution, recent development, size, disciplinary foundation,
and internal structure. The next two sections further elaborate the research questions
and related research methodologies.
Research Questions
The most frequently debated issue of the 1990s has been the question of the state
of implementation research. Is this a field of investigation where the volume of
research has declined to the extent that it needs revitalization as many contemporary
commentators have suggested (Barrett, 2004; deLeon, 1999, 2002; Lester & Goggin,
1998; Schofield, 2001; Schofield & Sausman, 2004; Winter, 1999, 2003)? Perhaps the
opposite is the case as others had predicted at the outset of the previous decade
(Goggin et al., 1990)?
Saetren: Facts and Myths about Implementation Research 561
There is no doubt that the volume of research on public policy implementation
has grown substantially since the mid-1970s, but exactly how large is it at the begin-
ning of the new millennium? Can this question be answered at all, or even approx-
imately? If so, what is the answer?
Political science scholars and their colleagues in the subfields of public admin-
istration and public policy share the sacred notion that policy implementation
research is primarily their domain. Does this conviction withstand closer examina-
tion? If not, what are the other academic disciplines that make important contribu-
tions to implementation research?
The degree of concentration or fragmentation regarding the structure of scholarly
communication is essential to efforts at accumulation of knowledge in any field of
investigation (Borgman, 1990). The greater the number of articles published in a few
core journals the more favorable the condition should be for synthesizing that
research literature and vice versa. How does implementation research fare in this
vital respect?
It is customarily asserted that virtually no research under the explicit label of
implementation (or implementing) was carried out before the publication of Press-
man and Wildavsky’s seminal book titled Implementation in 1973. Is this really true?
In the same vein it might be reasonably assumed that implementation research orig-
inated on the West Coast in the San Francisco Bay Area at the University of
California Berkeley campus, where Wildavsky was an influential teacher and
researcher during the 1960s and 1970s. Do the facts corroborate this?
What policy issues do implementation scholars study and how do they match
the supposedly salient ones in our societies? This question also has a geographical
dimension. There is no doubt that implementation research from the beginning was
predominantly a North American enterprise. The question here is to what extent the
focus has shifted to other regions of the world and their policy challenges as the
research field matured?
Another key issue is the relevance of implementation research, and why it
became unfashionable. Finally, one wonders if some policy scholars’ recent calls for
the revival of implementation research are having any effect. If so, what direction
should reenergized research efforts take? These, then, are the main questions this
article purports to answer.
Data and Methodology
As most reviewers of implementation research have had little to say about their
data sources and methodologies, I find it necessary to rectify this neglect. This study
has relied on many data sources and research methods. Nonetheless, digitalized,
scientific literature databases presently available at most universities as well as a
related search instrument called bibliometrics,1 proved to be the most important by
far. Three databases in particular, the Expanded Social Science Citation Index, World
Catalogue, and the Digital Dissertations (Dissertation Abstracts), were utilized because
they are interdisciplinary and together they cover all major types of publications.
They contain vast amounts of information, but of variable quality.2 Still, there are
562 Policy Studies Journal, 33:4
some pieces of relevant information concerning publications listed in the databases
that are not consistently registered. This applied especially to: (i) abstracts; (ii)
authors’ background (professional and national), whether their publications are
empirically oriented or not; (iii) research methodology employed; (iv) policy sector
studied; and (v) regional focus. These deficiencies constituted the main rationale for
creating our own electronically indexed and retrievable literature data file based on
the Cardbox software program.
Conceptual and practical matters related to searches in the three literature data-
bases are discussed in the section below that deals with the size estimate issue where
they are of particular relevance.
Research Results
The Alleged Demise of Implementation Research
In the early 1990s scholars like Goggin et al. (1990, 9) were quite upbeat about
the future of implementation research, proclaiming interest “is likely to grow during
the 1990s and continue well into the twenty-first century. In fact, the field of public
policy in the next decade will very likely be defined by the focus on implementa-
tion. The nineties are likely to be the implementation era”(italics in original).
This optimistic view, however, lost ground during the latter part of the 1990s as
it dawned upon an increasing number of scholars that it might be misplaced. Saetren
(1996) presented some preliminary data to the effect that a pronounced and steady
decline in research publications on policy implementation from 1984 up to 1995 had
occurred. At approximately the same time Hill (1997) and Lester and Goggin (1998)
arrived at the same conclusion. Other commentators in recent years have also var-
iously subscribed to the thesis of decline (Barrett, 2004; Hill & Hupe, 2002; O’Toole,
2000, 2004; Schofield, 2001; Schofield & Sausman, 2004; Winter, 2003). The facts of
the matter would then seem to have been settled fairly and squarely in favor of the
decline thesis. Not quite! It turns out that we can all be simultaneously right and
wrong, depending on how we qualify our statements.
If the total picture is examined, that is, all publications jointly (Figure 1), the
data overwhelmingly refute the decline proposition. Although publications peaked
and declined somewhat during the mid-1980s, their numbers had bounced back
well before the end of that decade. Moreover, the trend continued unabated, even
growing beyond previous levels through the 1990s and into the twenty-first century.
This exponential growth amounted to the near doubling of publications during the
period after 1984 compared with the previous period (Table 1). Although the output
of some publications increased more rapidly than others, over time none of these
trends lend support to a demise or decline thesis.
This constitutes a paradox. How can it be that so many scholars us came to
believe that the interest in implementation research had declined to an alarmingly
low level? How did the exponential growth of research literature reported here
escape our attention? The next section, which explores the disciplinary structure of
implementation research, provides some clues to an answer.
Saetren: Facts and Myths about Implementation Research 563
Exploring the Disciplinary Foundation of Implementation Research
Many authors have long believed that studies of policy implementation are
mostly carried out by those who have an interest either in political science in
general, or in public administration and public policy in particular. This notion may
seem to follow logically from the fact that a more fundamental understanding of
implementation as an integral part of the public policy process must draw upon and
bridge insights from these fields of knowledge (Winter, 2003). This is also our justi-
fication for defining journals in these three subfields as the core. The heretical ques-
tion raised here is: Does such a core really exist?
The implication of this credo is that we should expect a clear majority of arti-
cles on policy implementation to be published in core journals. Table 2 clearly shows
that such is not the case at all. Articles published in noncore journals far outnum-
ber those appearing in core journals. An alternative and more modest expectation
can be derived from one of the so-called laws of bibliometrics, namely Bradford’s
law. It states that journals in any field of investigation can be divided into three main
categories, each containing roughly the same number of articles: (i) a nucleus of rel-
atively few journals on the subject publishing approximately one-third of all arti-
cles, defined as the core; (ii) another group consisting of many more journals that
produces approximately the same number of articles, referred to as near-core; and
(iii) an even more distant category of a still larger number of journals—the truly
Table 1. Publications by Type and Two Time Periods
Type of Publication 1933–84 1985–2003 Total
Articles 1,094 2,429 3,523
Books and chapters 323 682 1,005
PhD dissertations 1,091 1,682 2,773
Total 2,498 4,803 7,301
Note: Absolute values are used for the data presented in this table.
0
50
100
150
200
25
N
u
m
b
er
Year
0
300
350
400
1
9
3
3
1
9
3
8
1
9
4
3
1
9
4
8
1
9
5
3
1
9
5
8
1
9
6
3
1
9
6
8
1
9
7
3
1
9
7
8
1
9
8
3
1
9
8
8
1
9
9
3
1
9
9
8
2
0
0
3
Article
B o o k s
Chapters
PhD dissertations
Total
Figure 1. Publications on Policy Implementation by Type and Year.
564 Policy Studies Journal, 33:4
noncore—which accounts for the last third of articles (Potter, 1988). To test this thesis
I divided all journals registered in a database into these same categories.3
The data (Table 2) even repudiate this moderated expectation of Bradford’s law.
Only in 1980 (Table 3) did I come close to attaining the law’s prediction, as 30 percent
of all articles published that year were actually published in core journals. It is,
however, clearly an exception to the general rule. Only 13 percent of all implemen-
tation articles between 1942 and 2003 were published in core journals. Another 14
percent appeared in the near-core category. Doctoral dissertations reveal a similar
pattern (not shown in Table 2) as approximately 15 percent of all are classified as
belonging to the core fields of political science or public administration. This means
that about three-fourths or more of these two types of publication were located
outside the core.
What academic disciplines, then, constitute the noncore group? It turns out that
education and health journals each account for 15 percent of all implementation arti-
cles (Table 2). Journals devoted to law, economics, and the environment are also impor-
tant as they jointly account for another 14 percent. The education profession figures
much more prominently among doctoral dissertations, as close to two-thirds have
this affiliation. These data attest to the pronounced multidisciplinary character of
research on public policy implementation and a surprisingly modest contribution
of scholars from the core fields. They also help explain why so many of us have
been oblivious to the continued rapid growth of implementation research during
the 1990s: it happened disproportionately in other academic fields and in a bewil-
dering array of different and largely peripheral journals (see Table 4) to which we
could not pay much attention, even if so desired. There are, in other words, good
excuses for our previous ignorance.
Even looking at the core journals, the decline notion cannot be sustained. The
volume of articles in these journals did peak during the mid-1980s and subsequently
stabilized at a somewhat lower level (Figure 2). It would, however, be rather far-
fetched to claim, as some do, that the whole research field has virtually disappeared.
In fact the number of articles in core journals almost doubled during the period from
1985 compared with the previous period. Why then is the notion of the demise of
implementation research so prevalent in spite of facts that clearly suggest the contrary?
Table 2. Articles by type of journal and time periods
Type of journal 1948–1984 1985–2003 Total
Core 15% (159) 12% (295) 13% (454)
Near core 9% (97) 16% (379) 14% (476)
Non-core 76% (838) 72% (1,755) 73% (2,593)
Total 100% (1,094) 100% (2,429) 100% (3,523)
Non-core specified:
Health 12% (126) 16% (384) 15% (510)
Education 17% (178) 14% (330) 15% (508)
Law 12% (131) 5% (131) 7% (262)
Environment 4% (41) 6% (144) 5% (185)
Economics 3% (31) 3% (74) 3% (105)
Other non-core 29% (331) 28% (692) 29% (1,023)
Note: Absolute values are in parentheses.
Saetren: Facts and Myths about Implementation Research 565
Table 3. Several Measures of Fragmentation of Scholarly Communication in the Journal Literature on
Public Policy Implementation for Selected Years
1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000
Number of articles in core journals 1 6 30 20 12 17 16
Number of different core journals in 1 5 14 10 10 13 14
which they were published
Journals to articles ratio in core 1 : 1 83% 47% 50% 83% 77% 88%
category
Number of articles in noncore 22 31 70 67 86 117 137
journals
Number of different noncore 22 27 64 60 78 110 120
journals in which they were
published
Journals to articles ratio in noncore 1 : 1 87% 91% 90% 91% 94% 88%
category
Percentage of all articles in core 4% 16% 30% 23% 12% 13% 11%
journals
0
50
100
150
N
u
m
b
er
Year
200
250
300
1
9
3
3
1
9
3
9
1
9
4
4
1
9
4
9
1
9
5
4
1
9
5
9
1
9
6
4
1
9
6
9
1
9
7
4
1
9
7
9
1
9
8
4
1
9
8
9
1
9
9
4
1
9
9
9
Core
Noncore
Figure 2. Articles on Policy Implementation Published in Core and Noncore Journals
by Year of Publication.
Table 4. Articles on Public Policy Implementation in Core Journals by Type of Journal
and Time Period
1953–79 1980–84 1985–89 1990–94 1995–99 2000–03 Total
Political science 22% (12) 17% (18) 17% (18) 20% (12) 21% (16) 23% (13) 20% (89)
Public policy 46% (25) 65% (68) 48% (50) 44% (26) 38% (29) 32% (18) 47% (216)
Public administration 32% (17) 18% (19) 35% (37) 36% (21) 41% (31) 45% (25) 33% (150)
(N) = 100% (54) (105) (105) (59) (76) (56) (454)
Note: Absolute values are in parentheses.
566 Policy Studies Journal, 33:4
The paradox must also be explained by the surprising fact that implementation
research, despite its resilience in quantitative terms, went out of fashion among policy
scholars after a relative short peak period that lasted only through the first half of
the 1980s. It is symptomatic that the last symposium on policy implementation
research was published in Policy Studies Review in the late 1980s.4 Even stronger and
more convincing support for this interpretation is provided by data on the number
of book reviews on policy implementation in journals included in the Social Science
Citation Index. Fifty-five percent of all book reviews (Table 5) appeared during the
relative short period from 1980 to 1985 and only 16 percent date after 1990. We have
already seen how the declining interest in implementation studies from around the
mid-1980s coincided with a temporary stagnation and drop in publication output.
More interestingly, the fact that publication volume returned to previous levels
toward the end of the 1980s and has continued unabatedly ever since at even a
higher level did not mean that implementation research had once again become
fashionable among policy scholars.
Thus, Goggin et al. (1990) were simultaneously both right and wrong. Imple-
mentation research continued to grow as they predicted during the 1990s and into
the twenty-first century. The field of public policy during the same period however,
has not been defined by its focus on implementation. On the contrary, even leading
policy scholars came to regard implementation focus as an intellectual “dead end”
and has turned their attention toward other topics such as policy change, policy net-
works, or governance. Indeed, implementation studies became so unfashionable that
even those who still considered them important mistakenly thought they had essen-
tially disappeared. This erroneous notion was exacerbated by a myopic disciplinary
conception of the research field.
Fortunately, as I have pointed out, the interest in policy implementation studies
has been profound and widespread enough to defy narrow disciplinary boundaries.
Thus, its fate has been insulated from the impact of whimsical fashion trends among
scholars in any particular academic field, such as political science.
The Structure of Scholarly Communication
The previous analysis suggests that the structure of scholarly communication
in implementation research is quite fragmented. To corroborate this we need to take
a closer look at the ratio of articles to the number of different journals in which they
were published (fragmentation ratio). Our findings (Table 3) lend strong support to
the fragmentation hypothesis. At the alleged infancy of implementation studies in
1970, the 23 articles were published in an equally different number of journals (i.e.,
Table 5. Reviews of Books with Policy Implementation as the Key Word in Social Science Citation
Index Journals by Time Period
Time Period 1972–79 1980–85 1986–90 1991–95 1996–99 2000–03 Total
Book reviews 7% (6) 55% (48) 23% (20) 8% (7) 2% (2) 6% (5) 101% (88)
Note: Absolute values are in parentheses.
Saetren: Facts and Myths about Implementation Research 567
a perfectly fragmented publication pattern). Only one article was published in a core
journal. The closest we came to the opposite pattern, and that implied by Bradford’s
law, was in 1980 when one (core) journal (Policy Studies Journal) accounted for 18
percent of all articles published that year. Nevertheless, even in that year, the one
hundred articles published appeared in 78 different journals; 14 of which were of
the core type. This fragmented publication pattern obviously poses great challenges
for any efforts at systematic knowledge accumulation.
A Closer Look at the Core
The core consists of close to 60 different journals that collectively published 454
implementation articles over a 60-year time period (see Appendix 1). Approximately
half of these articles were published in public policy journals, one-third in public
administration journals, and one-fifth in political science journals (Table 4). It is note-
worthy that the position of public administration journals relative to policy journals
has been reversed during the 1990s compared to earlier. This pattern seems to reflect
a growing interest in implementation research among editors and contributors to
public administration journals during the 1990s. The emergence of the Journal of
Public Administration Research and Theory in the late 1980s is but one of several indi-
cators of this trend. The relatively modest but stable fraction of articles published
in political science journals is also worth noticing.
Two policy journals—Policy Studies Journal and Policy Studies Review—published
the largest share of core articles followed by the Public Administration Review. These
three journals alone published 30 percent of the total. At the other end of the spec-
trum we have the prestigious American Political Science Review with only three arti-
cles, none of which are cited frequently.
The documented explosive growth of implementation research, even in recent
years, invites the intriguing question of what its present size might be. The next
section attempts to provide an approximate answer.
What Is the Size of the Implementation Literature?
Few, if any, serious efforts have ever been made to estimate the total volume of
research on public policy implementation, and for good reason: it is a very demand-
ing and difficult task. Some have even concluded that it is a futile endeavor (Hill &
Hupe, 2002). To this I would counter that even having only an approximate esti-
mate is better than having no clue at all. Furthermore, as others have emphasized,
knowing something about the scale of the total universe of publications in any
research area is a prerequisite as well as the starting point for any serious synthe-
sizing efforts (Cooper & Hedges, 1994).
There appears to be only three earlier attempts to assess the volume of research
on public policy implementation (Hill & Hupe, 2002; O’Toole, 1986; Sinclair, 2001).
They were, however, as far as we can ascertain, limited to a particular type of
publication and time period. I know of no systematic attempt to document the
volume of several types of publication over an extended time period.
568 Policy Studies Journal, 33:4
The universe of any research literature is located in a three-dimensional space.
First, what concepts are most appropriate to identify the relevant literature? Second,
what types of publications are to be searched with chosen key words? Third, what is
the time frame for such searches? In this study, implementation as title-word was the
preferred choice since Pressman and Wildavsky were so instrumental in populariz-
ing the use of this term with regard to studies of policy execution.5 Although this
choice can be challenged,6 it is justified as follows. First, the term implementation
helps to establish a well-defined body of literature that can be retrieved by others
and subjected to replication and critical examination. Second, I think it is reason-
able to assume, as others have done before me (Sinclair, 2001, 81), that those who
want to make a contribution toward the understanding of policy implementation
are more prone to using either implementation or implementing as title words than
those who do not share this goal. The latter group is obviously more peripheral to
our mapping enterprise than the former.
Publications vary from journal articles, books, book chapters, doctoral dissertations,
reports, to research papers to name the most common ones in the reference literature.
We chose to focus primarily on the first four mentioned above. The time frame was
extended as far as the databases allowed. I found approximately 7,300 English pub-
lications using implementation or implementing as a title word, after eliminating
the most obviously irrelevant ones for our analysis.7 Table 1 shows their distribu-
tion by types of publication: 548 books, 432 book chapters, 3,523 journal articles, and
2,773 doctoral dissertations.8 The most surprising in this respect was the large
number of doctoral dissertations, both in absolute terms and relative to the two
other types of publications. They are obviously an unexplored and untapped, rich
source for future efforts to synthesize research results.
To conclude, it is impossible to pinpoint with much precision the true size of
research publications on policy implementation. Any size estimate critically
depends on a number of steps and related judgment calls taken by the researcher
during the search procedures.9 In that sense it remains an elusive utopian ideal.
Nonetheless, I think our database is sufficiently large to ensure a reasonably approx-
imate representation of the policy implementation literature as a whole. Now it is
time to turn to the question of the origin of this elusive universe.
When Did Implementation Research Start?
The truism that Pressman and Wildavsky (1973) pioneered the more explicit use
of implementation as a key term was in no small part created by the authors them-
selves in a postscript chapter, Appendix 2, titled “Use of ‘Implementation’ in Social
Science Literature”:
There is (or there must be) a large literature about implementation in the
social sciences—or so we have been told by numerous people. None of them
can come up with specific citations to this literature but they are certain it
must exist”. . . . “It must be there, it should be there, but in fact it is not”
. . . “How shall we persuade others that it is fruitless to look for a literature
that does not exist? . . . (p. 166)
Saetren: Facts and Myths about Implementation Research 569
It has since been pointed out that many earlier scholars had studied the imple-
mentation of policies using other labels. Few, however, have …
The Implementation of Public Policy:
Still the Missing Link
Robbie Waters Robichau and Laurence E. Lynn Jr.
Although theories of public policy and theories of governance both seek to establish relationships
between policymaking and its consequences, they do not complement each other very well. Public policy
models tend to de-emphasize that which governance theories tend to emphasize: the influence on
government performance of implementation, broadly described as the actions taken by those engaged in
administration (including managers at all levels, those engaged in service delivery, and third-party
agents) after a policy has been lawfully promulgated by elected officials and interpreted by the courts.
A comparison of a recently developed theory of public sector performance with several prominent
theories of policymaking suggests that multilevel governance theories can supply what continues to be
the missing link in public policy theories. At the same time, governance theories might be enriched by
the process modeling of public policy theories.
Introduction
The increasing use of “governance” as a conceptual frame for research on the
determinants of government performance has produced valuable insights into causal
relationships among public choice processes, public management, service delivery,
and citizen and stakeholder assessments and reactions. Paralleling these efforts,
public policy theorists have developed a variety of models to depict relationships
between policymaking processes and their outputs and outcomes. Although both
types of research seek to relate policymaking to its consequences, they do not
complement each other very well. Public policy models tend to de-emphasize that
which governance theories tend to emphasize: the influence on government perfor-
mance of implementation through administrative systems, broadly described as the
actions taken by public managers at all levels, those engaged in service delivery, and
third-party agents after a policy has been promulgated by elected officials and
interpreted by the courts.
This article offers a preliminary consideration of how theories of governance and
of public policy might better complement each other. We juxtapose a theory of
Prepared for presentation at the Next Generation Policy Workshop in Norman, Oklahoma,
February 27–29, 2008.
The Policy Studies Journal, Vol. 37, No. 1, 2009
21
0190-292X © 2009 Policy Studies Organization
Published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc., 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ.
government performance that features the influence of administrative systems on
outputs and outcomes (Forbes, Lynn, & Robichau, 2008) with some of the major
public policy theories found in Sabatier’s edited volume, Theories of the Policy Process
(Sabatier, 2007). We will argue that, because they do not conceptualize the distinction
between policy outputs and policy outcomes, public policy theories tend to slight
the administrative processes that constitute implementation. Erwin Hargrove
argued in 1975 that implementation was the missing link in the study of public policy
(Hargrove, 1975). As we see it, that link is still missing. We will show how even a
parsimonious theory of public sector performance framed by a logic of governance
(LOG) can provide the missing link.
The discussion will proceed as follows. The next section explains why and how
an “LOG” framework was used to develop a theory of public sector performance.
The description of this theory will be used to provide insights into how and why
government produces its outputs and outcomes. The article will then analyze several
public policy theories in relation to what they are missing and neglecting to study,
that is, the failure to distinguish between outputs and outcomes and the disregard
of administrators’ and administrative systems’ impacts on policy outcomes. We will
conclude with a discussion of how using governance theory can advance public
policy theorizing and suggest that governance theories might be similarly enriched
by public policy theories.
A Theory of Public Sector Performance
Public governance is defined in this article, following Lynn, Heinrich, and Hill
(2001, p. 7), as “regimes of laws, rules, judicial decisions, and administrative prac-
tices that constrain, prescribe, and enable the provision of publicly supported goods
and services” through formal and informal relationships with third parties in the
public and private sectors. Using concepts from positive political economy, Lynn,
Heinrich, and Hill develop a multilevel “LOG” that postulates that politics, public
policymaking, public management, and service delivery are hierarchically linked
with one another in the determination of public policy outputs and outcomes.
A large body of research uses hierarchical logic when designing empirical
studies of governance and public management (Boyne, 2003; Boyne, Meier, O’Toole,
& Walker, 2006; Forbes, Hill, & Lynn, 2006, 2007; Forbes & Lynn, 2005; Forbes et al.,
2008; Heinrich, 2003; Hill & Lynn, 2005; Lynn, Heinrich, & Hill, 2001). Being suffi-
ciently confirmed in theory and in the empirical research literature, the multilevel
LOG was used by Forbes, Lynn, and Robichau as the point of departure for a theory
of public sector performance which focuses on the operations of the administrative
system in the determination of government performance (Forbes et al., 2008). A brief
explanation of how the theory was developed will set the stage for showing how
public policy theories can benefit from the governance literature and, in particular,
the implementation process.
Development of the multilevel theory of public sector performance used in this
article drew on findings from an analysis of nearly thirteen hundred published
empirical studies, each of which incorporated hierarchical and causal relationships
22 Policy Studies Journal, 37:1
among at least two levels of governance. The original LOG analyses categorized each
study’s dependent and independent variables at each level under investigation using
the scheme in Table 1 (e.g., in Hill & Lynn, 2005; Forbes et al., 2006, 2007). Policy
studies are more likely to inform levels of citizen interests and preferences, public
choice and policy design, outputs/outcomes and, to a lesser extent, stakeholder
assessments than variables found at the management and service delivery level,
which ultimately lie at the heart of policy output production.
In subsequent analyses by Forbes et al. (2008), Scott’s conceptualization of orga-
nizational effectiveness indicators were used to reclassify the independent and
dependent variables in each study (Scott, 2003; Scott & Davis, 2007). Scott says that
“proponents of rational, natural, and open system models privilege differing indi-
cators of effectiveness” that can nonetheless be grouped into three general indicator
Table 1. Logic of Governance Levels and Variables
Citizen preferences and interests expressed politically
1. Expressions of citizen preferences and interests
2. Activities of private firms and organizations
3. Activities of interest groups
Public choice and policy designs
1. Socioeconomic context
2. Level/type of government (e.g., state, council/manager)
3. Political atmosphere
4. Fiscal situation/budget constraints
5. Type of ownership (public, nonprofit, proprietary)
6. Mandates by internal government entities (e.g., Office of Management and Budget)
7. Mandates by elected executives
8. Mandates by legislatures
9. Court decisions
10. Other
Public management
1. Initiation of administrative structures
2. Usage of management tools (policy planning, total quality management)
3. Management values and strategies
Service delivery
1. Initiation of program design features
2. Fieldworker/office discretionary behavior
3. Fieldworker/office beliefs and values
4. Initiation of administrative processes and policies
5. Work/treatment/intervention
6. Client influence, behavior, and/or preference (coproduction)
7. Use of resources
Outputs/outcomes
Outputs; means to an end
1. By government/public sector
2. By markets/firms/private sector
3. By individuals/society
Outcomes; ends
1. By government/public sector
2. By markets/firms/private sector
3. By individuals/society
Stakeholder assessments of policy, agency, or program performance
Robichau/Lynn: The Missing Link 23
types that “point to important distinctions regarding what is being assessed” (Scott
& Davis, 2007, p. 327).
Scott’s typology of effectiveness indicators has three categories: structures, pro-
cesses, and outcomes. Structural indicators reflect the production function, that is,
the way the organization’s work is organized. Process indicators measure the quan-
tity or quality of the organization’s work, that is, effort or output. Outcome indicators
purport to identify changes in an individual or organization that have been the object
of some kind of intervention, service, or regulation. Thus, the effectiveness of each
level of governance can be measured in terms of some combination of structures,
processes, and outcomes.
Analyzing the multilevel governance literature using these indicators led to the
following findings. First, the presumption is warranted that implementation is gen-
erally hierarchical; influences flow downward through a chain of delegation to the
retail level of service delivery. Second, in the great majority of studies, policymaking
took the form of structures; that is, the primary function of policymaking was to
organize administrative systems to accomplish the purposes of public policies.
Third, within administrative systems, management, that is, the authorized and nec-
essary exercise of managerial discretion, took the form of a relatively balanced
combination of structures and processes. Finally, measures of service delivery effec-
tiveness were, in most cases, process indicators. The cumulative products of policy-
making, management, and service delivery consisted of outputs, which comprised
both process and outcome indicators of effectiveness, and the “final” outcomes of
policymaking and its implementation.1
These findings are incorporated by Forbes, Lynn, and Robichau into their
theory of public sector performance. Some of the findings were not so readily
accepted, however. For example, most of the investigations were oriented toward
outputs rather than outcomes. But few empirical models recognized or incorpo-
rated an outputs-cause-outcomes logic; most used either outputs or outcomes
without considering how outputs influence the ultimate outcomes of policies and
their implementation.
In Bureaucracy, James Q. Wilson (1989) helps helps us understand how outputs
and outcomes are related. Similar to Scott’s explanation, Wilson defines outputs as
“the work the agency does” and outcomes as “how, if at all, the world changes
because of the outputs” or “results” (p. 158). Grouping outputs as the “work” and
outcomes as the “results” enables scholars to think about the logical flow of cause
and effect relationships in governance and policy studies. Based on the empirical
findings concerning the political science and public administration literature, we
found that distinguishing between outcomes and outputs was both possible and
instrumental in advancing our theory of public sector performance.
It is possible, however, that, in special cases, outputs of an agency may be
unobservable and unknowable (Wilson, 1989). One consequence might be that some
agencies will be able to see only outcomes without knowing how outputs influenced
them. If outcomes are undesirable, then an agency faces the challenge of trying to
decide how to fix the problem without knowing whether it is a question of structure
or process. For example, a program like Head Start provides various services, such as
24 Policy Studies Journal, 37:1
education, health care, parental education and involvement, and nutritious meals
to underprivileged children. They claim that children in their programs show
improved cognitive and language abilities as well as higher health status ratings
when compared to their peer groups (National Head Start Association, 2008); yet, it
is hard to say which services produce which results. Outcomes could be produced
from any one of these provisions or a combination of services, thereby making the
determination of outputs unknowable and unobservable.
Wilson (1989) proceeds to create a typology of four kinds of government agen-
cies based on the extent to which both outcomes and outputs are observable and
measurable. He categorizes these agencies as: production (where outcomes and
outputs are recognizable); procedural (where outputs not outcomes are observable);
craft (where outcomes not outputs are distinguishable); and finally, coping organi-
zations (where neither outcomes nor outputs can be observed) (pp. 158–71).
This useful heuristic has a twofold consequence for thinking about both gover-
nance and policy theories. First, how administrators manage their agencies will be
dependent on the type of agency in which they work and whether they focus on
processes or outcomes. And second, either outcomes and/or outputs are frequently
observable; therefore, they can often be measured or at least considered in agency
performance. Wilson (1989) states that “people matter, but organization matters also,
and tasks matter most of all” (p. 173). If we think of tasks as the work agencies and
their agents produce, then depicting outputs as necessary to achieving outcomes
seems intuitive.
Further, a significant number of studies “skipped” levels in the LOG, excluding,
for example, the mediating effects of management or service delivery in transform-
ing policy structures into outputs and outcomes (see Figure 1). The percentages in
Figure 1 are proportions of the total studies in the database that employ this particu-
lar causal logic. In the absence of convincing substantive reasons for excluding these
Management
Structures
Service
Delivery
Processes
Enacted Policy
Structures
Outputs/
Outcomes
9% (Skip levels)
2.7% (No skip)
6.8% (Skip levels)
3.5% (No skip)
7.3% 3.5%
6.6%
Management
Processes
13.1% 8.0%
Figure 1. Empirically Modeled Governance Relationships.
Robichau/Lynn: The Missing Link 25
mediating effects from explanatory models, there is a high likelihood that the find-
ings of such studies are incomplete or biased. In their analysis of studies concerned
with health policy implementation, Forbe et al. (2007) concluded that “in general, the
choices of organizational arrangements, administrative strategies, treatment quality,
and other aspects of health care services by policymakers, public managers, physi-
cians, and service workers, together with their values and attitudes toward their
work, have significant effects on how health-care policies are transformed into
service-delivery outputs and outcomes” (p. 453).
The basic theory, then, incorporates both outputs-cause-outcomes logic and all
mediating levels (unless it can be plausibly argued that policies have been designed
so as to be self-executing, thus requiring little managerial intervention). The theory
of public sector performance is depicted in Figure 2. It consists of hierarchically
related public policymaking structures,2 management structures and processes,
service delivery processes, outputs, and outcomes, with an acknowledgement of
self-executing policies.
Public Policymaking
Structures
Management Structures &
Management Processes
Service Delivery
Processes
Outputs as Processes
Outcomes
Environment/Policy Context
Figure 2. Theory of Public Sector Performance.
*The dotted line represents potential modeling patterns that skip the management level and represent
public policies that are self-executing.
26 Policy Studies Journal, 37:1
It is important to note that these relationships all occur within a social, economic,
and political context. Whereas these contextual considerations may influence gover-
nance at any level in complex ways, the theory assumes that such contextual influ-
ences do not nullify the fundamental hierarchical logic that links the multiple levels
of governance, a logic that is the consequence of America’s constitutional scheme of
governance, which defines the American version of the rule of law.
The implications of this theory have the potential to contribute to public policy
theorizing. First, given the hierarchical nature of governance, it is difficult, if not
impossible, for policy outputs and outcomes to be produced without administrative
systems. Further, it is difficult to imagine that public policy outcomes can occur
without administrative system outputs. In part for this reason (and in part because
outputs are easier to measure), administrative systems tend to be output-, not
outcome-oriented.
Analyzing Policy Theories
With the above discussion as a point of departure, we next examined a selection
of the public policy theories included in Sabatier (2007). This examination reveals
two problematic aspects of these theories: the failure to distinguish between outputs
and outcomes and the imprecise treatment of the role of administrative systems in
mediating the relationship of policymaking to its ultimate consequences.
Outputs and Outcomes
Sabatier (2007) notes that Institutional Rational Choice (IRC) theory is “clearly
the most developed of all the frameworks in this volume” (p. 9). In her chapter, on
IRC theory, Ostrom discusses an action arena where actors and action situations
occur that can lead to predicting outcomes inside this arena. Then, her framework
moves from this arena to patterns of interactions, followed by outcomes, in which
both are moderated by evaluated criteria. Ostrom (2007, p. 33) states that “evaluative
criteria are applied to both the outcomes and the processes of achieving outcomes.”
But these “processes” are not clearly defined, partly, it would appear, because
outputs and outcomes have not been differentiated.
Other policy theories exhibit similar ambiguity concerning outputs and out-
comes. For instance, the Multiple Streams (MS) Framework is sensitive to how
information affects choice and how inputs gets transformed to outputs; yet, Zaha-
riadis (2007) does not clearly define what he means by “policy outputs” in this
chapter. It might be the case that outputs are simply decisions (good or bad) that
have been made, the actual policy that is produced from decisions made, or perhaps,
both of them combined.
Another policy approach that can be seen as providing vague descriptions about
outputs and outcomes is the Network Approach. Adam and Kriesi (2007) state that
“the impact of policy networks clearly shows that network structures are not only
connected to specific policy outcomes (‘what’) but also to the type of change (‘how’)
that creates these outcomes. A systematic analysis of the impact of policy networks
Robichau/Lynn: The Missing Link 27
requires that the types of networks be linked to the potential for and types of change
creating different outcomes” (p. 145). If outputs are regarded as the “work” of an
agency or in this case, the “work” of a network, then the reference to “outcomes”
seems inappropriate.
Finally, the Social Construction and Policy Design framework (Ingram,
Schneider, & deLeon, 2007) has an inherent output focus, which becomes particu-
larly apparent when examining their propositions and diagram.3 The fundamental
idea of this framework is that future policy design stems from past and current
policy designs. Moreover, these policy designs are mediated by institutions, culture,
and target populations, followed by society and policymaking dynamics (p. 96). But
outputs, as distinguished from outcomes, are not clearly defined.
One policy theory acknowledges a distinction between outputs and outcomes.
The Advocacy Coalition Framework (ACF) depicts a relationship where policy
outputs precede policy impacts (Sabatier & Weible, 2007, p. 202). But, this part of the
policy subsystem, in our reading, is not defined or discussed in Sabatier and Weible’s
chapter or in the previous models of ACF (Sabatier & Jenkins-Smith, 1999).
From a governance perspective, lack of clarity concerning the distinction
between outputs and outcomes is problematic. As discussed earlier, outcomes and
outputs have distinguishable characteristics (Donabedian, 1966; Hall, 1999; Scott,
1977, 2003; Scott & Davis, 2007; Suchman, 1967). It is hard to tell whether policy
theorists assume that those working in the field know the difference or, alternatively,
do not think that the difference is important. Our argument is that drawing clear
distinctions between outputs and outcomes is essential for understanding how
administrative systems are influenced by and, in turn, influence the consequences of
policymaking.
Administrators and Administration
Terry Moe (1990) crafts a theory of the public bureaucracy that takes into account
politics and political organization in a two-tiered hierarchy in which “one tier is the
internal hierarchy of the agency, and the other is the political control structure
linking it to politicians and groups” (p. 122). Designed around the politics of bureau-
cratic structures, Moe emphasizes how political uncertainty and the need for com-
promise leads to rational bargaining among political actors that, in the end, produces
technically irrational agencies. In other words, administrative systems are designed
more to protect political bargains struck in order to guard various stakeholder
interests than as to facilitate the achievement of outputs and outcomes.
Our examination of the public policy theories discussed in the previous section
suggests that the performance of administrative systems is not generally held to be
of particular significance to public policy achievement. It seems intuitively clear,
however, that managers are in a position to use their discretion to shape the rela-
tionship between enacted policy structures and administrative system outputs.
Moreover, the analysis of empirical health policy studies cited earlier (Forbes et al.,
2006) supports this view. Wilson (1989) notes that public managers have preferences,
and in a similar vein, Sabatier and Weible (2007, pp. 194–96) contend that they are
28 Policy Studies Journal, 37:1
often influenced by “policy core beliefs.” Lindblom and Woodhouse (1993) claim
that “administrators indeed are policymakers” (p. 62). A convincing literature has
established the influential role in policy implementation played by “street-level
bureaucrats.” From a governance perspective, then, the relative neglect of adminis-
trative systems in public policy theories seems unwarranted.
We found that administrative systems are either referred to loosely through a
discussion of managerial influences on the policymaking process or they are ignored
altogether. The Institutional Analysis Framework, for example, is vague on whether
the “action arena” and/or the “patterns of interactions” could be seen as places
where bureaucracy and its’ administrators enable outputs to be achieved. Perhaps,
the framework is set up so that administrative influences and implementation occur
in both arenas, but without specific discussion of these matters, we are left wonder-
ing why such a vital part of the policy process was not discussed explicitly.
Similarly, the MS Framework considers bureaucrats as part of the policy com-
munity that is involved in the policy stream, but no logic linking administrators as
policy entrepreneurs to administrative system outputs is indicated. Authors of the
Network Approach examine how coalitions or networks are formed. They claim that
these coalitions are composed of either “state actors” or “system of interest inter-
mediation” (Adam & Kriesi, 2007, p. 134). Adam and Kriesi specifically and clearly
define those who belong to the “system of interest intermediation” as “political
parties, interest groups, and nongovernmental organizations/social movement orga-
nizations” (p. 134). These authors’ explanation of “state actors,” however, is ambigu-
ous; “state actors constitute a special type, because they ‘have access to a very
particular resource: their decisions are considered binding in society and are backed
by the possibility of legitimate use of force’ ” (p. 134). In this context, state actors
could be viewed as legislators, judges, political appointees, or administrators. For
governance scholars, greater clarity and specificity of when, or even if, administra-
tors and their agencies are involved in the policy process is essential.
Administrative Systems
Of even greater concern than the vague references to administrators is that
administrative systems as part of the policy process are left out entirely. Policy
process theories tend to analyze the progression of policy development through
design and negotiation, and then assume that policy outcomes are a result of par-
ticular policies. Yet, external policymaking is only the first stage in the logic of how
outputs and outcomes are produced.
To see the issue more clearly, several theories of the policy process have been
modified to demonstrate visually the point that policy process theories have missing
links that are logically and empirically essential to the determination of government
performance. Graphically lacing the theory of the public sector performance to some
of the major policy process theories enables us to see how they can complement one
another in providing further explanatory specificity to current policy and gover-
nance theories. By rotating the figures of policy process theories to a vertical orien-
tation, a new and clearer picture emerges about what these theories are emphasizing
Robichau/Lynn: The Missing Link 29
from a governance perspective. Policy theories appear to be focusing primarily on
the public choice and policy level of governance and at the output/outcome level,
thus, in effect skipping the mediating levels of administration.
The model most closely approximating the LOG is the IRC framework (see
Figure 3). Ostrom does consider levels of analysis (i.e., operational, collective choice,
constitutional, and metaconstitutional) intermediate to outcomes in her IRC model.
However, her main focus is on the effects of rules (which are governance structures)
at each level. Her framework might be expanded to include more discussion of the
relationships of administrative systems to structures and processes beyond rules. In
Figure 3, though, it is difficult to tell whether policymaking structures, management
structures and processes, service delivery processes, and outputs as processes all
occur in the action arena, in the patterns of interactions, or various links occur before
the action arena or even after patterns of interactions.
In examining the MS Framework, it must first be noted that Zahariadis (2007,
p. 65) regards this framework as one that “could conceivably be extended to cover
the entire process of policymaking at various levels of government, it is examined
here only in its capacity to explain policy formation (agenda setting and decision
making).” Despite this caveat, locating where “policy outputs” occur in the poli-
cymaking environment is challenging but nonetheless necessary in developing
better theories of the policy process. Perhaps “policy outputs” could follow the
policymaking structures, or they could be at the lower level of outputs as pro-
cesses in comparison to the theory of public sector performance (see Figure 4). If
Attributes of
Community
Physical/Material
Conditions
Actors
Action Arena
Action
Situations
Rules-In-Use
Patterns of
Interactions
Outcomes
Evaluative Criteria
Environment/Policy Context
Public Policymaking
Structures
Management Structures &
Management Processes
Service Delivery
Processes
Outputs as Processes
Outcomes
Figure 3. A Framework for Institutional Analysis Modified Hierarchically from Sabatier (2007, p. 27)
Juxtaposed with the Theory of Public Sector Performance.
30 Policy Studies Journal, 37:1
the MS framework is to be expanded to account for the complete policy process or
used by governance scholars to obtain greater insight into the policy process, then
one step in doing so would be to clarify the role of administrative systems in
output production. Zahariadis contends that some critics of this framework ques-
tion whether the three steams are independent of one another and that “stream
independence is a conceptual device” (p. 81). In the comparison to the theory of
public sector performance, all three streams would fall into a larger category of
public policymaking.
The Network Approach is juxtaposed with the theory of public sector perfor-
mance in Figure 5. Although Adam and Kriesi (2007) note that depicting network
structures as being vertically organized violates network premises, doing so does
produce an interesting way of thinking about the structures and processes of net-
works and how they interact with other levels of governance. The “structure of
policy networks” …
CATEGORIES
Economics
Nursing
Applied Sciences
Psychology
Science
Management
Computer Science
Human Resource Management
Accounting
Information Systems
English
Anatomy
Operations Management
Sociology
Literature
Education
Business & Finance
Marketing
Engineering
Statistics
Biology
Political Science
Reading
History
Financial markets
Philosophy
Mathematics
Law
Criminal
Architecture and Design
Government
Social Science
World history
Chemistry
Humanities
Business Finance
Writing
Programming
Telecommunications Engineering
Geography
Physics
Spanish
ach
e. Embedded Entrepreneurship
f. Three Social Entrepreneurship Models
g. Social-Founder Identity
h. Micros-enterprise Development
Outcomes
Subset 2. Indigenous Entrepreneurship Approaches (Outside of Canada)
a. Indigenous Australian Entrepreneurs Exami
Calculus
(people influence of
others) processes that you perceived occurs in this specific Institution Select one of the forms of stratification highlighted (focus on inter the intersectionalities
of these three) to reflect and analyze the potential ways these (
American history
Pharmacology
Ancient history
. Also
Numerical analysis
Environmental science
Electrical Engineering
Precalculus
Physiology
Civil Engineering
Electronic Engineering
ness Horizons
Algebra
Geology
Physical chemistry
nt
When considering both O
lassrooms
Civil
Probability
ions
Identify a specific consumer product that you or your family have used for quite some time. This might be a branded smartphone (if you have used several versions over the years)
or the court to consider in its deliberations. Locard’s exchange principle argues that during the commission of a crime
Chemical Engineering
Ecology
aragraphs (meaning 25 sentences or more). Your assignment may be more than 5 paragraphs but not less.
INSTRUCTIONS:
To access the FNU Online Library for journals and articles you can go the FNU library link here:
https://www.fnu.edu/library/
In order to
n that draws upon the theoretical reading to explain and contextualize the design choices. Be sure to directly quote or paraphrase the reading
ce to the vaccine. Your campaign must educate and inform the audience on the benefits but also create for safe and open dialogue. A key metric of your campaign will be the direct increase in numbers.
Key outcomes: The approach that you take must be clear
Mechanical Engineering
Organic chemistry
Geometry
nment
Topic
You will need to pick one topic for your project (5 pts)
Literature search
You will need to perform a literature search for your topic
Geophysics
you been involved with a company doing a redesign of business processes
Communication on Customer Relations. Discuss how two-way communication on social media channels impacts businesses both positively and negatively. Provide any personal examples from your experience
od pressure and hypertension via a community-wide intervention that targets the problem across the lifespan (i.e. includes all ages).
Develop a community-wide intervention to reduce elevated blood pressure and hypertension in the State of Alabama that in
in body of the report
Conclusions
References (8 References Minimum)
*** Words count = 2000 words.
*** In-Text Citations and References using Harvard style.
*** In Task section I’ve chose (Economic issues in overseas contracting)"
Electromagnetism
w or quality improvement; it was just all part of good nursing care. The goal for quality improvement is to monitor patient outcomes using statistics for comparison to standards of care for different diseases
e a 1 to 2 slide Microsoft PowerPoint presentation on the different models of case management. Include speaker notes... .....Describe three different models of case management.
visual representations of information. They can include numbers
SSAY
ame workbook for all 3 milestones. You do not need to download a new copy for Milestones 2 or 3. When you submit Milestone 3
pages):
Provide a description of an existing intervention in Canada
making the appropriate buying decisions in an ethical and professional manner.
Topic: Purchasing and Technology
You read about blockchain ledger technology. Now do some additional research out on the Internet and share your URL with the rest of the class
be aware of which features their competitors are opting to include so the product development teams can design similar or enhanced features to attract more of the market. The more unique
low (The Top Health Industry Trends to Watch in 2015) to assist you with this discussion.
https://youtu.be/fRym_jyuBc0
Next year the $2.8 trillion U.S. healthcare industry will finally begin to look and feel more like the rest of the business wo
evidence-based primary care curriculum. Throughout your nurse practitioner program
Vignette
Understanding Gender Fluidity
Providing Inclusive Quality Care
Affirming Clinical Encounters
Conclusion
References
Nurse Practitioner Knowledge
Mechanics
and word limit is unit as a guide only.
The assessment may be re-attempted on two further occasions (maximum three attempts in total). All assessments must be resubmitted 3 days within receiving your unsatisfactory grade. You must clearly indicate “Re-su
Trigonometry
Article writing
Other
5. June 29
After the components sending to the manufacturing house
1. In 1972 the Furman v. Georgia case resulted in a decision that would put action into motion. Furman was originally sentenced to death because of a murder he committed in Georgia but the court debated whether or not this was a violation of his 8th amend
One of the first conflicts that would need to be investigated would be whether the human service professional followed the responsibility to client ethical standard. While developing a relationship with client it is important to clarify that if danger or
Ethical behavior is a critical topic in the workplace because the impact of it can make or break a business
No matter which type of health care organization
With a direct sale
During the pandemic
Computers are being used to monitor the spread of outbreaks in different areas of the world and with this record
3. Furman v. Georgia is a U.S Supreme Court case that resolves around the Eighth Amendments ban on cruel and unsual punishment in death penalty cases. The Furman v. Georgia case was based on Furman being convicted of murder in Georgia. Furman was caught i
One major ethical conflict that may arise in my investigation is the Responsibility to Client in both Standard 3 and Standard 4 of the Ethical Standards for Human Service Professionals (2015). Making sure we do not disclose information without consent ev
4. Identify two examples of real world problems that you have observed in your personal
Summary & Evaluation: Reference & 188. Academic Search Ultimate
Ethics
We can mention at least one example of how the violation of ethical standards can be prevented. Many organizations promote ethical self-regulation by creating moral codes to help direct their business activities
*DDB is used for the first three years
For example
The inbound logistics for William Instrument refer to purchase components from various electronic firms. During the purchase process William need to consider the quality and price of the components. In this case
4. A U.S. Supreme Court case known as Furman v. Georgia (1972) is a landmark case that involved Eighth Amendment’s ban of unusual and cruel punishment in death penalty cases (Furman v. Georgia (1972)
With covid coming into place
In my opinion
with
Not necessarily all home buyers are the same! When you choose to work with we buy ugly houses Baltimore & nationwide USA
The ability to view ourselves from an unbiased perspective allows us to critically assess our personal strengths and weaknesses. This is an important step in the process of finding the right resources for our personal learning style. Ego and pride can be
· By Day 1 of this week
While you must form your answers to the questions below from our assigned reading material
CliftonLarsonAllen LLP (2013)
5 The family dynamic is awkward at first since the most outgoing and straight forward person in the family in Linda
Urien
The most important benefit of my statistical analysis would be the accuracy with which I interpret the data. The greatest obstacle
From a similar but larger point of view
4 In order to get the entire family to come back for another session I would suggest coming in on a day the restaurant is not open
When seeking to identify a patient’s health condition
After viewing the you tube videos on prayer
Your paper must be at least two pages in length (not counting the title and reference pages)
The word assimilate is negative to me. I believe everyone should learn about a country that they are going to live in. It doesnt mean that they have to believe that everything in America is better than where they came from. It means that they care enough
Data collection
Single Subject Chris is a social worker in a geriatric case management program located in a midsize Northeastern town. She has an MSW and is part of a team of case managers that likes to continuously improve on its practice. The team is currently using an
I would start off with Linda on repeating her options for the child and going over what she is feeling with each option. I would want to find out what she is afraid of. I would avoid asking her any “why” questions because I want her to be in the here an
Summarize the advantages and disadvantages of using an Internet site as means of collecting data for psychological research (Comp 2.1) 25.0\% Summarization of the advantages and disadvantages of using an Internet site as means of collecting data for psych
Identify the type of research used in a chosen study
Compose a 1
Optics
effect relationship becomes more difficult—as the researcher cannot enact total control of another person even in an experimental environment. Social workers serve clients in highly complex real-world environments. Clients often implement recommended inte
I think knowing more about you will allow you to be able to choose the right resources
Be 4 pages in length
soft MB-920 dumps review and documentation and high-quality listing pdf MB-920 braindumps also recommended and approved by Microsoft experts. The practical test
g
One thing you will need to do in college is learn how to find and use references. References support your ideas. College-level work must be supported by research. You are expected to do that for this paper. You will research
Elaborate on any potential confounds or ethical concerns while participating in the psychological study 20.0\% Elaboration on any potential confounds or ethical concerns while participating in the psychological study is missing. Elaboration on any potenti
3 The first thing I would do in the family’s first session is develop a genogram of the family to get an idea of all the individuals who play a major role in Linda’s life. After establishing where each member is in relation to the family
A Health in All Policies approach
Note: The requirements outlined below correspond to the grading criteria in the scoring guide. At a minimum
Chen
Read Connecting Communities and Complexity: A Case Study in Creating the Conditions for Transformational Change
Read Reflections on Cultural Humility
Read A Basic Guide to ABCD Community Organizing
Use the bolded black section and sub-section titles below to organize your paper. For each section
Losinski forwarded the article on a priority basis to Mary Scott
Losinksi wanted details on use of the ED at CGH. He asked the administrative resident