8-3 - Accounting
The purpose of this assignment is to assess state taxation and the concept of apportionment. You will prepare a memo (750-1,000 words) for a client who is considering expanding business in multiple states. XYZ Corporation is your client and you regularly communicate with the CFO, Danny Client.
XYZ Corporation is a calendar year taxpayer that manufacturers equipment for businesses in Arizona, Kansas, and Oklahoma. XYZ has manufacturing facilities in Arizona and Oklahoma. There are various employees who reside and work in Kansas. The company headquarters are located in Arizona. A number of employees based in Arizona travel to Colorado and Utah to solicit sales from potential customers. After products are delivered to customers in Colorado and Utah, XYZ sends employees to install the products and conduct training. XYZ generates $100,200,000 of total revenue for all of its locations.
In the memo, address the following:
Summarize the client facts. Use your own words.
Determine the client issues: Does XYZ have income tax nexus in Colorado and Utah?
Provide advisory services by explaining the concept of nexus to the CFO, Danny Client, using the information from Public Law 86-272.
Summarize the apportionment and allocations that would apply to XYZ if the company is required to file tax returns in Colorado and Utah. Describe the apportionment items and details on how the apportionment is calculated for both states.
Provide the CFO with details of the potential tax and financial impact to XYZ Corporation for conducting business in multiple states.
While APA style is not required for the body of this assignment, solid academic writing is expected, and documentation of sources should be presented using APA formatting guidelines, which can be found in the APA Style Guide, located in the Student Success Center.
This assignment uses a rubric. Please review the rubric prior to beginning the assignment to become familiar with the expectations for successful completion.
You are required to submit this assignment to LopesWrite. Refer to the LopesWrite Technical Support articles for assistance.
Benchmark Information
This benchmark assignment assesses the following programmatic competencies:
MS Accounting
3.2: Demonstrate the skills required to apply that knowledge in providing tax preparation and advisory services and performing other responsibilities as certified public accountants.
JOURNAL OF PASSTHROUGH ENTITIES 21
January–February 2014
State Law & State Taxation Corner
By John A. Biek
New York and Illinois High Courts Take Divergent Views of the
Constitutionality of State “Click-Through Nexus” Laws
John A. Biek is a Partner in the Tax Prac-
tice Group of Neal, Gerber & Eisenberg
LLP in Chicago, Illinois.
Introduction
One of these columns from the spring of 20111
discussed two New York lower court decisions in
Amazon.com, LLC v. New York State Department
of Taxation and Finance that turned back facial
Commerce Clause challenges to the New York
“Amazon Law” or “click-through nexus” law.2 First
enacted by New York in 2008, and subsequently
adopted by another dozen states, these laws create
a rebuttable presumption that an out-of-state re-
mote seller is required to collect the state’s use tax
on its interstate sales transactions with customers
in the state if (1) the remote seller has contractual
arrangements with in-state persons (referred to in
the industry as “Internet affi liates”) to refer cus-
tomers through a computer link from the Internet
affi liate’s website to the remote seller’s website,
(2) the remote seller is paying the Internet affi liate
compensation based on the amount of sales rev-
enue that the remote seller generates from these
referrals and (3) the remote seller generates more
than $10,000 of sales annually from such referrals
from Internet affi liates.3 The theory of these click-
through nexus laws is that these performance-based
website referral arrangements are probably ac-
companied by in-state physical sales solicitation
activity by the Internet affi liate, which would give
the remote seller use tax-collection nexus under
well-established case law.4
Litigation is seldom a speedy endeavor and, in
March 2013, some four years after the original New
York Amazon.com decision, the New York Court of
Appeals—the highest court in the state—affi rmed the
Read "State Law and State Taxation Corner," by Biek, from Journal of Passthrough Entities (2014).
URL:
https://lopes.idm.oclc.org/login?url=http://search.ebscohost.com.lopes.idm.oclc.org/login.aspxdirect=true&db=bth&AN=93744292&site=ehost-live&scope=site
22 ©2014 CCH Incorporated. All Rights Reserved.
constitutionality of the New York click-through nexus
law.5 On December 2, 2013, the U.S. Supreme Court
declined to review this ruling.
Meanwhile, the Illinois Supreme Court issued a
somewhat surprising ruling on October 18, 2013,
in Performance Marketing Association v. Hamer,6
upholding the circuit court’s determination in May
2012 that the Illinois click-through nexus law is
preempted by the federal Internet Tax Freedom Act
(the “ITFA”).7 The Amazon.com and Performance
Marketing Association decisions are not necessarily
in confl ict because of differences in the language
of the New York and Illinois click-through nexus
statutes and the legal theories on which these two
cases were decided. Signifi cantly, the Illinois click-
through nexus law conclusively presumes that the
remote seller has estab-
lished nexus in Illinois as
a result of its contractual
arrangements with in-
state Internet affi liates to
pay performance-based
compensation for their
website referrals to the
remote seller’s website, whereas the New York
click-through nexus only creates a rebuttable
presumption of nexus that the remote seller can
overcome by demonstrating that its instate Inter-
net affi liates have not engaged in actual physical
solicitation activity on behalf of the remote seller
in New York. Moreover, the Illinois Supreme Court
did not address the Commerce Clause argument in
the Performance Marketing Association case, basing
its decision solely on the ITFA. This appears to be
the fi rst case fi nding a state tax to be preempted by
that federal statute.
It is not really surprising that the U.S. Supreme
Court denied a writ of certiorari in the New York
Amazon.com and Overstock.com cases because of
the absence of a confl ict between the New York and
Illinois high court decisions and the fact that the New
York courts only decided the facial Commerce Clause
challenges to the New York click-through nexus law.
The New York Department of Taxation and Finance
is not asserting nexus against remote sellers that do
not allow their New York-based Internet affi liates to
engage in sales solicitation activity on behalf of the
remote seller in New York. Nevertheless, these New
York and Illinois court decisions have further mud-
died the constitutional waters of state click-through
nexus laws.
The New York Click-Through
Nexus Law
The New York click-through nexus stemmed from
concerns in 2008 that online merchants like Amazon.
com and Overstock.com were utilizing third-party
retail stores in New York and the websites of New
York-based youth sports clubs, schools, religious
institutions and other so-called “Internet affi liates”
with local audiences in the state to cross market the
online merchant’s products. The online merchant
would enter into a contract providing for the Inter-
net affi liate to create and promote a computer link
from its website to the on-line merchant’s website in
return for performance-based commissions based on
the volume of sales transactions that the online mer-
chant was able to make as
a result of these referrals
of the Internet affi liate’s
audience to the online
merchant’s website.
On April 28, 2008, the
N e w Yo r k A s s e m b l y
amended the definition
of “vendor” in the New York sales/use tax laws to
add the following Section 1101(b)(8)(vi):
a person making sales of tangible personal
property or services taxable under this article
(“Seller”) shall be presumed to be soliciting
business through an independent contractor
or other representative if the seller enters into
an agreement with a resident of this state un-
der which the resident, for a commission or
other consideration, directly or indirectly refers
potential customers, whether by a link on an
internet website or otherwise, to the seller, if
the cumulative gross receipts from sales by
the seller to customers in the state who are
referred to the seller by all residents with this
type of an agreement with the seller is in excess
of ten thousand dollars during the preceding
four quarterly periods ending on the last day
of February, May, August and November. This
presumption may be rebutted by proof that the
resident with whom the seller has an agree-
ment did not engage in any solicitation in the
state on behalf of the seller that would satisfy
the nexus requirement of the United States
Constitution during the four quarterly periods
in question.8
State Law & State Taxation Corner
Nevertheless, these New York and
Illinois court decisions have further
muddied the constitutional waters
of state click-through nexus laws.
JOURNAL OF PASSTHROUGH ENTITIES 23
January–February 2014
Crafting the New York click-through nexus law as
a rebuttable presumption that the in-state Internet
affi liates were acting as sales representatives of the
remote seller proved to be clever because it allowed
the New York courts to uphold the constitutionality
of the statute. Indeed, within two weeks of the fi ling
of Amazon’s declaratory judgment action alleging
that the New York click-through nexus law was
unconstitutionally imposing a use tax collection ob-
ligation on out-of-state vendors without any physical
presence in New York, contrary to the holding of the
U.S. Supreme Court in Quill Corp. v. North Dakota,9
the New York Department of Taxation and Finance
clarifi ed the scope of the New York click-through
nexus law in Technical Services Bureau Memoran-
dum TSB-M-08(3)S.10 This document explained, fi rst,
that the rebuttable presumption of nexus in Section
1001(b)(8)(vi) would be triggered only by the pay-
ment of commission-based fee compensation to the
New York-based Internet affi liate, as opposed to a
fl at-fee advertising arrangement that did not take into
account the dollar amount of sales that the Internet
affi liate’s referral activities were generating for the
remote seller.
TSB-M-08(3)S went on to explain that “[f]or pur-
poses of administering the new presumption, the
Tax Department will deem the presumption rebut-
ted where the seller is able to establish that the only
activity of its resident representatives in New York
State on behalf of the seller is a link provided on the
representatives’ Web sites to the seller’s Web site and
none of the resident representatives engage in any
solicitation activity in the state targeted at potential
New York State customers on behalf of the seller.”
Indeed, Example 6 in TSB-M-08(3)S described a fact
pattern in which several New York ski clubs that main-
tained links to remote seller XYZ’s website were paid
commissions based on the amount of sales resulting
from those links, but none of the ski clubs referred
potential customers to XYZ through the distribution of
fl yers, newsletters, telephone calls or emails to club
members or any other means of in-state solicitation
targeted at potential New York customers on behalf of
XYZ. Under those circumstances, TSB-M-08(3)S con-
cluded, XYZ had successfully rebutted the statutory
presumption that XYZ had established use tax collec-
tion nexus in New York as a result of its performance
marketing arrangement with the in-state ski clubs.
On June 30, 2008, the Department issued a
second Technical Services Bureau Memorandum,
TSB-M-08(3.1)S, explaining that a remote seller
could avoid the presumption of nexus under Sec-
tion 1101(b)(8)(vi) if (1) the remote seller included
a provision in its business referral agreements with
Internet affi liates prohibiting them from “engaging in
any solicitation activities in New York State that refer
potential customers to the seller” and (2) the remote
seller obtained annual signed certifi cations from the
Internet affi liates that they had not actually engaged
in such solicitation activities in New York during the
previous year.11
On January 12, 2009, Judge Eileen Bransten of the
Supreme Court for New York County (the trial court)
granted the department’s motion to dismiss all of the
counts in Amazon’s complaint for failure to state a
claim. Judge Bransten rejected Amazon’s claim that
the New York click-through nexus law is facially in-
valid under the Commerce Clause, concluding that:
The statute is targeted at requiring tax collection
when an out-of-state seller avails itself of the
benefi t of in-state contractors compensated for
referrals. As an added safeguard the Commis-
sion-Agreement Provision makes plain that a
seller does not have to collect taxes so long as
its New York contractors “did not engage in any
solicitation in the state [on its behalf] that would
satisfy the nexus requirement of the United States
Constitution.” Thus, a seller is afforded the op-
portunity to prove that none of its contractors
actively sought sales on its behalf in New York.12
Judge Bransten was not persuaded by Amazon’s
argument that the New York click-through nexus
law creates nexus out of “simple advertising by
in-state advertisers.” Rather, Judge Bransten found
that the New York statute “imposes a tax-collection
obligation on sellers who contractually agree to
compensate New York residents for business that
they generate and not simply for publicity.”13 Judge
Bransten believed that what was really happening
under these performance marketing arrangements
was that “Amazon chooses to benefi t from New
York Associates that are free to target New Yorkers
and encourage Amazon sales, all the while earning
money for Amazon in return for which Amazon pays
them commissions. Amazon does not discourage its
Associates from reaching out to customers or con-
tributors and pressing Amazon sales.”14
Judge Bransten determined that the New York
click-through nexus law would not violate the Com-
merce Clause as applied to Amazon, either, even if
24 ©2014 CCH Incorporated. All Rights Reserved.
Amazon could show that its Internet affi liates were
not soliciting business in New York at Amazon’s di-
rection or behest. In Judge Bransten’s view, because
Amazon gave its Internet affi liates an economic
incentive to engage in local solicitation activity on
behalf of Amazon, that solicitation activity was prob-
ably occurring on behalf of Amazon.15 Indeed, Judge
Bransten observed, Amazon had made no allegation
in its complaint that its in-state Internet affi liates were
not physically soliciting sales orders from New York
customers for Amazon in New York.16
For similar reasons, Judge Bransten dismissed all of
the claims in Overstock’s complaint.17
On November 4, 2010, the Supreme Court, Appel-
late Division, affi rmed Judge Bransten’s conclusion
that the New York click-
through nexus law does
not facially violate the
Commerce Clause. The
three-judge Appellate Di-
vision panel found that the
New York click-through
nexus law “imposes a tax
collection obligation on
an out-of-state vendor
only where the vendor
enters into a business-referral agreement with a New
York resident, and only when that resident receives
a commission based on a sale in New York.”18 The
Appellate Division added:
Of equal importance to the requirement that the
out-of-state vendor have an in-state presence is
that there must be solicitation, not passive adver-
tising. While Tax Law §1101(b)(8)(vi) creates the
presumption that the in-state agent will solicit, it
provides the out-of-state vendor with a ready es-
cape hatch or safe harbor. The vendor merely has
to include in its contract with the in-state vendor
a provision prohibiting the in-state representative
from “engaging in any solicitation activities in
New York State that refer potential customers to
the seller,” and the in-state representative must
provide an annual certifi cation that it has not
engaged in any prohibited solicitation activi-
ties as outlined in the memorandum. Thus, an
in-state resident which merely acts as a conduit
for linkage with the out-of-state vendor will be
presumed to have not engaged in activity which
would require the vendor to collect sales taxes.
Presumably, there are vendors which will be able
to execute the annual certifi cation without fear
of making a misrepresentation.19
Indeed, the Appellate Division was not able to
reconcile Amazon’s argument that its Internet af-
fi liates were only engaging in passive advertising
in New York with the statement in the company’s
own Associates Program marketing materials that
“[o]ur compensation philosophy is simple: reward
Associates for their contributions to our business in
unit volume and growth. Amazon is a fast growing
business and we want our Associates to grow with
us. . . . The performance structure allows you to earn
higher fees when you generate a suffi cient volume of
referrals that result in sales at Amazon.com during
a month. The higher your
referrals, the greater your
earnings will be.”20
However, the Appel-
late Division remanded
the Amazon.com and
Overstock.com cases to
the trial court for further
development of the tax-
payers’ claims that the
application of the New
York click-through nexus law to them violated the
Commerce Clause. Because no discovery had yet
been undertaken regarding Amazon’s and Overstock’s
referral arrangements with their in-state affi liates,
the Appellate Division was unable to conclude, as a
matter of law, that the in-state Internet affi liates were
“engaged in suffi ciently meaningful activity so as
to implicate the State’s taxing powers,” particularly
“whether their in-state representatives are soliciting
business or merely advertising on their behalf.”21
While this remand kept Amazon’s and Overstock’s
cases alive, these vendors may not have relished the
prospect of detailed discovery into their sales prac-
tices in New York.
Indeed, Amazon and Overstock abandoned their
as-applied Commerce Clause challenges when they
appealed the Appellate Division’s decision to the
New York Court of Appeals. On March 28, 2013, the
Court of Appeals affi rmed the conclusion of the two
lower courts that the New York click-through nexus
law constitutionally presumes that the remote seller’s
Internet affi liates are engaging in physical solicitation
activity in New York on behalf of the remote seller in
order to increase the amount of performance-based
compensation the affi liates receive from the remote
State Law & State Taxation Corner
Crafting the New York click-
through nexus law as a rebuttable
presumption that the in-state
Internet affi liates were acting as
sales representatives of the remote
seller proved to be clever[.]
JOURNAL OF PASSTHROUGH ENTITIES 25
January–February 2014
seller.22 The Court of Appeals noted in its opinion that
“no one disputes that a substantial nexus would be
lacking if New York residents were merely engaged
to post passive advertisements on their websites.23
However, the Court of Appeals agreed with the De-
partment’s argument that the New York click-through
nexus law was targeting physical solicitation activity
of the in-state Internet affi liates, which would consti-
tute more than mere advertising:
[T]hrough this statute, the legislature has at-
tached signifi cance to the physical presence of
a resident website owner. The decision to do
so recognizes that, even in the Internet world,
many websites are geared toward predominantly
local audiences—including, for instance, radio
stations, religious institutions and schools—such
that the physical presence of the website owner
becomes relevant to Commerce Clause analysis.
Indeed, the Appellate Division record in this case
contains examples of such websites urging their
local constituents to support them by making
purchases through their Amazon links. Essentially,
through these types of affi liation agreements, a
vendor is deemed to have established an in-state
sales force.24
The Court of Appeals concluded that:
Viewed in this manner the statute plainly satisfi es
the substantial nexus requirement. Active, in-state
solicitation that produces a signifi cant amount of
revenue qualifi es as “demonstrably more than a
‘slightest presence’” under Orvis. Although it is
not a dispositive factor, it also merits notice that
vendors are not required to pay these taxes out-
of-pocket. Rather, they are collecting taxes that
are unquestionably due, which are exceedingly
diffi cult to collect from the individual purchasers
themselves, and as to which there is no risk of
multiple taxation.25
The Court of Appeals drew on the same rationale
to reject Amazon’s and Overstock’s argument that the
New York click-through nexus law facially violated
the Due Process Clause by creating an irrational and
essentially irrebutable presumption of nexus. Accord-
ing to the Court of Appeals, “[i]t is plainly rational to
presume that, given the direct correlation between
referrals and compensation, it is likely that residents
will seek to increase their referrals by soliciting
customers, more specifi cally, it is not unreasonable
to presume that affi liated website owners residing
in New York State will reach out to their New York
friends, relatives and other local individuals in order
to accomplish their purpose.”26 Moreover, the New
York click-through nexus law affords the remote
seller some opportunity to rebut the presumption
of nexus by contractually prohibiting affi liates to
engage in physical solicitation activity in New York
on behalf of the remote seller and obtaining annual
certifi cates from all of the affi liates that they have
not undertaken such solicitation activity. The Court
of Appeals concluded that “[o]btaining the necessary
information may impose a burden on the retailers,
but inconvenience does not render the presumption
irrebuttable,” in violation of the Due Process Clause.27
The Illinois Click-Through
Nexus Law
The Illinois Supreme Court took a very different tack
in its review of the constitutionality of the Illinois
click-through nexus law in Performance Marketing
Association, Inc. v. Hamer.28 Enacted on March 10,
2011, as Public Act 96-1544, the Illinois click-through
nexus provision in Section 2 of the Illinois Use Tax
Law expanded the defi nition of a “retailer maintaining
a place of business in this State” to include:
a retailer having a contract with a person located
in this State under which the person, for a com-
mission or other consideration based upon the
sale of tangible personal property by the retailer,
directly or indirectly refers potential customers
to the retailer by a link on the person’s Internet
website. The provisions of this paragraph 1.1 shall
apply only if the cumulative gross receipts from
sales of tangible personal property by the retailer
to customers who are referred to the retailer by all
persons in this State under such contracts exceed
$10,000 during the preceding 4 quarterly periods
ending on the last day of March, June, September,
and December.29
Whereas the New York click-through nexus law
establishes a rebuttable presumption that the in-state
Internet affi liates are engaged in localized physical
sales solicitation activity in New York on behalf of
the remote seller, this Illinois click-through nexus
law conclusively presumes that such nexus has been
established as a result of the existence of the contrac-
26 ©2014 CCH Incorporated. All Rights Reserved.
tual performance marketing arrangement between
the remote seller and the Internet affi liate in Illinois.
The Illinois Department of Revenue did not have
much of an opportunity to develop administra-
tive guidance on how it would apply the Illinois
click-through nexus law because the Performance
Marketing Association (the “PMA”), a nonprofit
trade organization in Camarillo, California, that
represents the interests of businesses, organizations
and individuals using and supporting performance
marketing methods, including performance mar-
keting on the Internet, promptly fi led a lawsuit in
the Circuit Court of Cook County challenging the
constitutionality of the Illinois click-through nexus
statute. The PMA’s complaint for declaratory and
injunctive relief alleged that the Illinois click-through
nexus law violated the Commerce Clause because
the statute imposed a use
tax collection obligation
on remote sellers lack-
ing the physical presence
in Illinois required by
the U.S. Supreme Court’s
decision in Quill Corp.
v. North Dakota.30 The
PMA’s complaint further
alleged that the Illinois
click-through nexus law violates the federal Internet
Tax Freedom Act by affording more onerous nexus
treatment to Internet-based performance marketing
arrangements than performance marketing by print
or broadcast methods.31
The PMA and the Department entered into a de-
tailed joint stipulation of facts that described the
sorts of performance marketing activity that could
trigger sales and use tax nexus under the Illinois
click-through nexus law. The parties stipulated that
“[o]ther Internet retailers affected by P.A. 96-1544
have no physical presence in Illinois, but maintain
websites offering goods and/or services to consumers
throughout the country, and sell products and services
to consumers in Illinois and elsewhere from facilities
located outside the state, by using instrumentalities of
interstate commerce, including the Internet, and also
enter into contracts with Internet affi liates located in
Illinois, and make sales to consumers who access
their websites through links on the websites of such
Illinois Internet affi liates.”32 Much of this performance
marketing was directed at a regional, national or
international audience on the Internet rather than
specifi cally at Illinois consumers.33
The Department also stipulated that:
Under P.A. 96-1544, a retailer will be included
within the defi nition of a ‘retailer maintaining a
place of business in this State’ if: (1) the retailer has
a contract with an Internet affi liate with a physical
presence in Illinois for placement of text or images
on its (the Internet affi liate’s) website that include a
link that connects an Internet user to the retailer’s
website; (2) the Internet affi liate receives compen-
sation based upon sales by the retailer to such
customers; and (3) the retailer receives more than
$10,000 total gross receipts in the previous four
quarters from sales to customers who are referred
to the retailers by Internet affi liates in Illinois. Under
the amendments to 35 ILCS 105/2 and 35 ILCS
110/2 set forth in P.A. 96-1544, the retailer does not
need to have a physical
presence in Illinois; the
retailer’s contracts with
Internet affi liates alone
are suffi cient.34
Thus, whereas in the
Amazon.com case the
New York Department of
Taxation and Finance ar-
gued that the rebuttable presumption of nexus in the
New York click-through nexus law was justifi ed by
the in-state physical solicitation activity that in-state
Internet affi liates were presumably conducting on
behalf of the remote seller, the Illinois Department
of Revenue took the forthright position in the Per-
formance Marketing Association case that the mere
existence of the contractual performance marketing
arrangement between the remote seller and its in-
state Internet affi liate gives the remote seller nexus
in Illinois. The department agreed this was the case
even though “[c]onsumers generally do not know,
and have no way of knowing, the physical location,
including the state or even the country, where the
computer servers hosting a website are located. This
includes the websites of Internet affi liates and retailers
engaged in performance marketing.”35 This was hardly
the traditional face-to-face sales solicitation activity
that courts have considered over the years in their
cases fi nding use tax collection nexus.
The PMA and the department also stipulated that
performance marketing is not unique to the Internet. It
is commonly used in online sales because of the ease
of tracking consumer purchases and the role that a
State Law & State Taxation Corner
The Illinois Supreme Court’s
opinion in the Performance
Marketing Association cases leaves a
hollow feeling for many state tax
practitioners and taxpayers.
JOURNAL OF PASSTHROUGH ENTITIES 27
January–February 2014
link from an Internet affi liate’s website to the remote
seller’s website played in generating that sale.36 How-
ever, the parties agreed that “[o]ffl ine, performance
marketing is often used where some other method
permits the retailer to track the promotion and deter-
mine the level of response to and/or sales resulting
from the promotion. Examples would be the use of
promotional codes in print and on radio.”37
On May 7, 2012, the Circuit Court of Cook County
issued a brief order granting summary judgment to
the PMA on both its facial Commerce Clause claim
and its Internet Tax Freedom Act claim.38 The Illinois
Department of Revenue was able to appeal the Circuit
Court’s decision directly to the Illinois Supreme Court
because the decision had invalidated the Illinois
click-through nexus law on constitutional grounds.
The Illinois Supreme Court surprised many observ-
ers when it punted on the Commerce Clause issue
and instead affi rmed that the Illinois click-through
nexus law is federally preempted by the ITFA.39 En-
acted by Congress in 1998, section 1101(a)(2) of the
ITFA prohibits a state from imposing “discriminatory
taxes on electronic commerce.”40 Section 1104(2)
(A)(iii) of the ITFA defi nes a “discriminatory tax”
in part as any tax “imposed by a State or political
subdivision thereof on electronic commerce that . . .
imposes an obligation to collect or pay the tax on a
different person or entity than in the case of transac-
tions involving similar property, goods, services, or
information accomplished through other means.”41
The PMA claimed that the Illinois click-through
nexus law presents such a federally preempted dis-
criminatory tax on electronic commerce because
the express language of the Illinois click-through
nexus law only describes performance compensated
sales referrals via a computer link from the Internet
affi liate’s website to the remote seller’s website. Per-
formance marketing via more traditional media such
as catalogs, magazines, newspapers, television and
radio were not, according to the PMA, covered by
the Illinois click-through nexus law. The Department
responded that another provision of the “retailer
maintaining a place of business in this State” defi ni-
tion in Section 2 of the Illinois Use Tax Act applies
to a “retailer, pursuant to a contract with a broad-
caster or …
State Taxation and the Reallocation
of Business Activity: Evidence from
Establishment-Level Data
Xavier Giroud
Columbia University, National Bureau of Economic Research, and Centre for Economic
Policy Research
Joshua Rauh
Stanford University, Hoover Institution, Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research,
and National Bureau of Economic Research
Using census microdata on multistate firms and their organizational
forms, we estimate the impact of state taxes on business activity. For
C corporations, employment and the number of establishments have
short-run corporate tax elasticities of 20.4 to 20.5 and do not vary with
changes in personal tax rates. Pass-through entity activities show tax
elasticities of 20.2 to 20.4 with respect to personal tax rates and are in-
variant with respect to corporate tax rates. Capital shows similar pat-
terns. Reallocation of productive resources to other states drives around
half the effect. The responses are strongest for firms in tradable and
footloose industries.
The impact of state business taxation on employment and capital has
been heavily debated in both academic and policy circles on both theo-
retical and empirical grounds. The public finance literature has long rec-
ognized that business taxation affects marginal incentives through effec-
We are grateful to Erik Hurst (the editor), four anonymous referees, Jeffrey Brown, Steve
Davis, William Gale, Austan Goolsbee, Jim Hines, Charles McLure, David Merriman, Holger
Mueller, Mitchell Petersen, James Poterba, Juan-Carlos Suarez Serrato, Amit Seru, Danny
Electronically published April 9, 2019
[ Journal of Political Economy, 2019, vol. 127, no. 3]
© 2019 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-3808/2019/12703-0007$10.00
1262
“State Taxation and the Reallocation of Business Activity: Evidence from
Establishment-Level Data,” by Giroud, from Journal of Political
Economy (2019).
URL:
https://lopes.idm.oclc.org/login?url=https://search.ebscohost.com/
login.aspx?direct=true&db=bth&AN=136771118&site=eds-
live&scope=site&custid=s8333196&groupid=main&profile=103280
tive marginal tax rates and the cost of capital (Hall and Jorgenson 1967;
Fullerton 1984). More recent literature shows that taxation can have a
strengthened impact on the discrete choice of business location through
the impact of average tax rates and overall profitability, particularly in
the presence of economic rents (Devereux and Griffith 2003; Auerbach
2006). On the other hand, increased business taxation might not have a
large effect on the level of hiring and investment if businesses can change
their activities to use more tax-favored production strategies or organiza-
tional forms or if tax revenues are spent on public goods that improve the
state’s business climate.1
An empirical literature starting with Carlton (1979, 1983) and Bartik
(1985), and surveyed in Bartik (1991), has studied the geographic loca-
tion decisions of new firms or establishments as a function of state tax and
other characteristics.2 Studies beginning with Helms (1985) and Wasy-
lenkoandMcGuire(1985),andmorerecentlyGale,Krupkin,andRueben
(2015) and Suarez Serrato and Zidar (2016), have used aggregated panel
data at the state, county, or industry level to examine the effect of state
and local taxes on economic growth, employment, or capital formation.3
And a rich literature has modeled the tax implications of firms’ choices of
whether to enter foreign markets, notably Devereux and Griffith (1998,
1 For example, Fajgelbaum et al. (2019) estimate firm and worker mobility and prefer-
ences for public services jointly in a spatial model.
2 Other papers taking various approaches to measuring the effect of tax policy on the
location of new plants or firms include Coughlin, Terza, and Arromdee (1991), Papke
(1991), Wasylenko (1991), Hines (1996), Guimaraes, Figueiredo, and Woodward (2003,
2004), Gabe and Bell (2004), Rathelot and Sillard (2008), and Brüllhart, Jametti, and
Schmidheiny (2012).
3 Earlier papers focusing on one municipal or geographic area include Grieson et al.
(1977) and Grieson (1980) on the New York City and Philadelphia income taxes, respec-
tively. Fox (1981) examines Cuyahoga County, Ohio, and Newman (1983) focuses on the
South. Papers following on the panel approach of Helms (1985) using aggregated panel
data include Papke (1987), Mofidi and Stone (1990), Goolsbee and Maydew (2000), Bania,
Gray, and Stone (2007), Reed (2008), Gale et al. (2015), and Suarez Serrato and Zidar
(2016). Moretti and Wilson (2017) use patent office data on the location of investors to
show that changes in state personal and corporate taxation have an effect on the geograph-
ical location of innovative activity.
Yagan, Owen Zidar, and Eric Zwick for helpful discussions and comments, and to seminar
participants at Chicago, Stanford, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Columbia, Whar-
ton,NewYorkUniversity,Yale,UniversityofCaliforniaLosAngeles,London Business School,
London School of Economics, Utah, Toronto, Tilburg, Erasmus, Bocconi, Lausanne, Lux-
emburg, the London Business School Causality Conference, the NBER Public Economics
meetings (fall 2015), the NBER Corporate Economics meetings (fall 2015), the 2015 Na-
tional Tax Association meetings, the 2016 American Economic Association meetings, the
2016 Texas Finance Festival, the 2016 Minnesota Corporate Finance Conference, and the
2016 Barcelona Graduate School of Economics Summer Forum. We thank David Colino,
Bryan Chang, and Young Soo Jang for research assistance. Any opinions and conclusions
expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of
the US Census Bureau. All results have been reviewed to ensure that no confidential infor-
mation is disclosed. Data sources and coding information are provided as supplementary
material online.
state taxation and the reallocation of business activity 1263
2003); see also Grubert and Mutti (2000), Devereux, Griffith, and Simpson
(2007), Devereux, Lockwood, and Redoano (2008), and Duranton, Go-
billon, and Overman (2011).
This line of work has faced two main challenges. First, tax policy is not
exogenously determined, so that ascribing a causal interpretation to cor-
relations between state tax changes and counts of businesses or employ-
ees has been problematic. The primary concern is that state governments
might change tax policy in anticipation of changing economic conditions.
In one approach to address this issue, Fox (1986), Holmes (1998), Hol-
combe and Lacombe (2004), and Ljungqvist and Smolyansky (2016) use
county-level data to study how state taxation affects business activity in bor-
der counties between states that change policies and those that do not.
The second challenge is that the studies have lacked comprehensive mi-
crodata at the establishment level, so that the decisions of individual busi-
nesses cannot be tracked over time, leaving uncertainty as to whether
firms are relocating their businesses to other regions or reducing the scale
of their operations.
This study uses comprehensive and disaggregated establishment-level
data from the US Census Bureau to examine the impact of state business
taxation on employment and capital. We focus on firms with establish-
ments in multiple states, which must set their organizational form at the
federal level to be applicable to all establishments. To measure an effect
of state tax policy on business activity, we begin by exploiting the fact that
the corporate tax code directly affects only firms organized as subchap-
ter C corporations, whereas firms organized as S corporations, partner-
ships, or sole proprietorships (so-called pass-through entities) are directly
affected only by the individual tax code and other business taxes.4 Our ap-
proach is therefore closely related to that of Yagan (2015), who investi-
gates the impact of dividend taxes using the distinction between S corpo-
rations and C corporations.5
Our study is unique in that we use fully disaggregated data at the firm
and establishment levels and distinguish between firms of different orga-
nizational form for tax purposes. This setting allows for separate mea-
surement of the effects of the corporate tax code on the activities of C cor-
4 Cooper et al. (2015) document that pass-through entities currently generate more
than half of US business income, having risen from much lower levels in the 1980s.
Goolsbee (2004) examines how firms adjust their organizational form with respect to state
taxes at the corporate level, an adjustment margin that we also consider in our data. Since
our sample firms all operate in multiple states, however, it is not surprising that we observe
quite little leakage out of the corporate sector for these firms as a result of state-level tax
policy.
5 Yagan (2015) uses the distinction between C corporations and S corporations to test
whether the 2003 dividend tax cut affected corporate investment, as only C corporations
are subject to the double taxation created by the taxes on capital income.
1264 journal of political economy
porations and of the effects of the personal tax code on the activities of
pass-through entities, as well as tests for cross-effects. Furthermore, the
establishment-level microdata allow us to disentangle reallocation versus
pure economic disincentives of taxation.
Our primary sample consists of all US establishments from 1977–2011
belonging to firms with at least 100 employees and having operations in
at least two states. On the extensive margin, we find that a 1 percentage
point increase (decrease) in the state corporate tax rate leads to the clos-
ing (opening) of 0.04 establishments belonging to firms organized as C
corporations in the state. This corresponds to an average change in the
number of establishments per C corporation of 0.5 percent. A similar
analysis shows that a 1 percentage point change in the state personal tax
rate affects the number of establishments in the state per pass-through
entity by 0.4 percent. The cross-correlations between pass-through activ-
ity and corporate tax rates, and between corporate activity and personal
tax rates, are zero.
On the intensive margin of number of employees per establishment,
we find very similar results. Furthermore, we find that the marginal effec-
tive tax rate (in the sense of Fullerton [1984]) has a larger point estimate
effect than the statutory rate on the intensive margin, consistent with the
predictions of Devereux and Griffith (1998, 2003).6 Focusing on manu-
facturing firms, we find that capital shows directional patterns similar to
labor in its response to taxation. The point estimates of the elasticities
are 31–35 percent smaller for capital, although the standard errors are
not large enough to reject the null hypothesis that the magnitude is the
same as the effect on labor.
Opposite effects of around half of these magnitudes are observed in re-
sponse to tax changes in the other states in which firms operate, so that
around half of the baseline effect is offset by reallocation of activity across
states. This lends strong support to the view that tax competition across
states is economically relevant and is consistent with findings by Davis
and Haltiwanger (1992) that emphasize the importance in the labor mar-
ket of shifts in the distribution of employment opportunities across work
sites. The remaining changes in establishments and employment reflect
either forgone economic activity or moving abroad.
Further analysis captures complexities, heterogeneity, and changes in
state tax codes regarding apportionment of income in multistate firms. If
a company has a physical presence in more than one state, the company
must apportion its profits according to each state’s apportionment fac-
6 The marginal effective tax rate captures differences in the impact of the statutory rate
on the firm’s marginal tax burden due to differences in the present value of depreciation
allowances and investment tax credits.
state taxation and the reallocation of business activity 1265
tor weights for property, payroll, and sales.7 We show that the response of
moving establishments, employees, and capital is greatest when the physi-
cal location of a firm’s employees and property carries a larger weight in
assigning the tax burden to a given state. Even when the location of sales
carries a larger weight, however, we find strong effects when rules are in
effect that mitigate the tax attractiveness of firms moving to high sales ap-
portionment states (so-called throwback and throwout rules).
We further address endogeneity concerns by adopting a narrative ap-
proach in the spirit of Romer and Romer (2010), focusing on the 161 tax
changes in the sample of more than 100 basis points. For changes that
were passed to deal with an inherited budget deficit or to achieve a long-
run goal—changes less likely to be correlated with confounding factors
that can affect output and economic activity—we find magnitudes very
similar to those in the full sample of establishments affected by these large
cuts. Around half of the effects are felt in the tax year in which the tax rate
changed, with the full force being felt in the following year. We further
augment the narrative approach by looking separately at tax changes at
the state level that occurred in response to windfalls and shocks from
the federal tax reform acts of 1981 and 1986, finding effects of magnitude
similar to those of the other large increases and cuts in the corporate and
personal tax rates.
Overall, our findings on the effects of corporate taxation are larger
than those found in work that has examined the impact of tax policy at
the national level, such as Mertens and Ravn (2014), which finds using
narrative approaches that a 1 percentage point cut in the average corpo-
rate income tax rate at the federal level raises employment by a maximum
of 0.3 percent. Tax competition across states roughly doubles the base-
line effects that would be found in the absence of firms’ ability to move
across states.
Our elasticities are significantly smaller than those of Suarez Serrato
and Zidar (2016), who use a 10-year establishment elasticity of 4 estimated
in reduced-form aggregated panel data to calibrate their incidence model.
We demonstrate that these differences are due in part to the time horizon
(we find elasticities of 1.2 using our identification strategy over 10 years),
but in greater part due to the fact that our identification strategy allows us
to control for state-level economic variation that may be correlated with
but not caused by tax changes. When we remove fixed effects that control
for composition effects and nontax reasons a given firm may choose to be
active in a given state, our estimates appear much closer to those in Suarez
7 Strictly speaking, a state might have the right to tax a firm even if the firm does not
have a physical presence. That is, physical presence is sufficient, but perhaps not necessary,
for what is called “taxable nexus.” For example, providing installation or technical support
of a product in a state can generate nexus.
1266 journal of political economy
Serrato and Zidar’s study. Our results therefore imply that the actual elas-
ticities for existing firms are between those implied by national-level re-
gressions such as those in Mertens and Ravn (2014) and regressions on ag-
gregated state-level data such as those in Suarez Serrato and Zidar (2016).
This paper is organized as follows. Section I reviews the background
and related literature on business taxation at the state level. Section II dis-
cusses the data and methodology, specifically the establishment-level data
fromtheUSCensusBureau,ourcompilationofchangesinstatetaxcodes,
the specifications, and the implementation of the robustness checks us-
ing the narrative approach and the changes in state tax policy induced
by federal legislation. Section III details the main results on the extensive
and intensive margins. Section IV provides evidence on heterogeneous
treatment effects and general equilibrium. Section V presents conclusions.
I. Background, Literature, and Conceptual
Framework
A. Business Taxation at the State Level
In many respects, the structure of state business taxation, and especially
the definition of income, follows the general outlines of federal tax law.
The decision of a firm to incorporate allows for limited liability and cen-
tralized management but opens the possibility of entity-level taxation un-
der the corporate tax code at the federal level (Congressional Budget Of-
fice 2012). Firms that are incorporated under subchapter C of the federal
tax code (C corporations) must pay tax at corporation tax rates. Owners
of these firms then pay individual taxes when they receive dividends from
the C corporations or when they realize capital gains. Firms that are in-
corporated under subchapter S of the federal tax code, as well as unin-
corporated firms organized as partnerships and sole proprietorships, are
deemed pass-through entities. Pass-through entities pay no tax at the firm
level, but rather pass all profits on to their owners, who must pay taxes im-
mediately on their profits. Firms can also organize as limited liability cor-
porations (LLCs), a structure that offers some of the benefits of corporate
organization, such as full liability protection, without necessarily being
subject to entity-level taxation under the federal corporate tax code.8
Most states have a standard corporate income tax on profits that re-
sembles the federal corporate income tax: taxable income is calculated
8 There are differences in the incentives that different types of firms face in choosing
these different forms of organization. For example, small business owners with losses have
a stronger incentive to choose pass-through taxation than corporate taxation when such an
election is available (Gordon and Cullen 2006). We consider the potential effects of such
heterogeneity in the analysis in several ways below.
state taxation and the reallocation of business activity 1267
starting with revenues net of allowable cost deductions, and then a cor-
porate tax rate is applied to the state’s apportioned share of taxable in-
come.9 However, as of the end of the sample, three states had no corpo-
rate income tax: Nevada, South Dakota, and Wyoming.10 Texas had no
corporate income tax until 1991. Four states taxed corporations in some
other way, usually a tax on gross receipts. Starting in 2005, Ohio began to
phase out its corporate franchise tax and phased in a Commercial Activ-
ities Tax, which applies a rate of 0.26 percent to taxable receipts of over
$1 million. Michigan had a Single Business Tax based on a value-added
calculation from 1975 onward. In 2008 it then began the phase-in of the
Michigan Business Tax, which had a base of gross receipts less purchases,
and then finally implemented a regular corporate income tax in 2012.
Washington has the Business and Occupation Tax, a gross-receipts tax,
during the entire sample period. Texas implemented a Corporate Fran-
chise Tax in 1992, which was then replaced by the Texas Margin Tax in
2008.
Further complicating the analysis of the effects of tax policy on corpo-
rate activity are the laws that differ by state as to how taxable income must
be apportioned for multistate firms for tax purposes. In contrast to the
federal tax treatment of multinational firms, which requires transfer prices
for intermediate production inputs moved by the firm across borders,
states use apportionment formulas that obviate the need for keeping track
of internal prices. In determining state-level tax liabilities, a firm must first
determine which states have the power to tax the business or, in tax termi-
nology, whether a company has “nexus” in a state. If a firm has a physical
presence in the state, specifically property or employees, then the state
clearly has the power to tax. If the firm does not have a physical presence
in the state and its activities are limited to “mere solicitation of orders,”
the state does not have the power to tax the firm.11 A firm must consider
the apportionment formula for each state in which it has nexus.12
Apportionment formulas are typically a function of the location of at
least one of three different measures of economic activity: sales, payroll,
and property. The apportionment formula effectively changes the cor-
porate income tax into a tax on each of the apportionment formula fac-
tors (McLure 1980, 1981). Gordon and Wilson (1986) show how appor-
9 States are not required to follow the federal definition of income in all respects, al-
though most state statutes incorporate the Uniform Division of Income for Tax Purposes
Act, a model act intended to create tax uniformity.
10 Nevada, however, has a payroll tax called the Modified Business Tax. This tax is not
included in the analysis.
11 The Interstate Income Act of 1959, referred to as Public Law 86-272, details conditions
under which a firm might lack physical presence in a state but still have nexus in the state.
12 Some variation exists in the way states tax pass-through entities with nonresident own-
ers. According to Baker Tilly (2014), more than 30 states “require pass-through entities to
withhold income tax on behalf of some or all owners—generally nonresidents.”
1268 journal of political economy
tionment approaches can create complex incentives both for multistate
firms and for state governments setting tax policy. At the beginning of
the sample period, virtually all states used an equally weighted formula,
but during the sample period there was a shift toward the use of single-
sales apportionment (i.e., a 100 percent weight on sales).
To illustrate by way of example, California had a one-third weight on
each of sales, payroll, and property until 1992. A firm with nexus in Cal-
ifornia would calculate the share of sales, share of payroll, and share of
property in California, and the average of these three components would
yield the percentage of the firm’s taxable income apportioned to Califor-
nia. From 1992 to 2010, the weights in California were 50 percent on
sales, 25 percent on payroll, and 25 percent on property.13 Relative to the
pre-1992 regime, firms with more sales in California but less physical pres-
ence had to allow more of their income to be taxed in California. Con-
versely, firms with few in-state sales but more physical presence saw a re-
duction in their tax burden. These changes went even further in 2011,
when California introduced an optional 100 percent weight on sales, and
in 2013, when the 100 percent sales weight became mandatory.
Under a pure single-sales apportionment factor, the only variable that
matters in apportioning income to the state (assuming the firm has nexus)
is what percentage of the firm’s sales were in the state itself. However,
some states (including California) have so-called throwback rules associ-
ated with their apportionment calculations, where states capture income
from sales to other states by requiring companies to add (or “throw back”)
sales that are made to buyers in a state where the company has no nexus,
sometimes called “nowhere income.” Three states (Maine, New Jersey,
and West Virginia) have a “throwout” rule instead of a “throwback” rule,
which accomplishes a similar goal, namely, to increase the relative weight
of in-state sales in the sales factor, thus increasing the income apportioned
to the taxing state. Under throwout rules, states capture the nowhere in-
come by requiring companies to subtract (or “throw out”) nowhere sales
from total sales, thereby reducing the denominator in the apportionment
calculation.
There has been relatively little empirical work studying the impact of
apportionment formulas. Using variation in the payroll weight across
states and over time, Goolsbee and Maydew (2000) demonstrate that the
within-state employment effect of reducing the payroll weight is, on aver-
age, substantial and that such a change has a negative effect on employ-
ment in other states. Gupta and Mills (2002) find suggestive evidence
that firms optimize reported sales locations in response to sales appor-
tionment factors. Klassen and Shackelford (1998) find that manufactur-
13 This is sometimes referred to as a “double-weighted” sales apportionment factor.
state taxation and the reallocation of business activity 1269
ing shipments from states that tax throwback sales are decreasing in the
corporate income tax rate on sales.
Businesses also pay an array of other taxes, notably sales taxes, unem-
ployment insurance contributions, and property taxes. Furthermore,
states often grant targeted tax incentives and financial assistance for spe-
cific industries. These taxes are not the primary focus of our paper, but we
do include controls for all of these factors in our analysis.
B. Conceptual Framework
The literature has used several different frameworks to model firm loca-
tion decisions as a function of tax policy. Early literature on the econom-
ics of the corporate income tax assessed its incidence and efficiency when
the corporate sector produced one set of goods and the noncorporate
sector another set of goods (Harberger 1962; Shoven 1976). In these clas-
sic settings, the corporate income tax resulted in a redistribution of re-
sources in the economy toward the goods produced by the noncorporate
sector and therefore a deadweight loss.14
These incidence models are relevant in that they recognize that more
mobile factors will escape taxes by flowing into sectors where they are not
taxed as heavily. To escape the heaviest tax burden, factors of production
may haveto be redeployed less efficiently. The originalintuitionfromHar-
berger (1962) was that, under a set of assumptions, a higher tax burden
would drive capital (whose supply is fixed in aggregate) from the taxed
into the untaxed sector, and in equilibrium the incidence of the tax would
be on the returns to capital in both sectors. Open economy analyses of
corporate tax incidence show immobile workers bearing the burden of
the tax through lower labor compensation, as capital moves to jurisdic-
tions where it will face lower taxes (McLure 1980, 1981; Kotlikoff and Sum-
mers 1987).15
The traditional incidence analyses feature a fixed stock of capital and
supply of labor making them not particularly suitable to a setting in which
firms can invest in new capital and potentially draw on or release surplus
labor. Furthermore, their primary goal is to explain the distribution of the
burden of the tax. The mobility of labor and capital is better seen as an ex-
planatory factor in their analyses.16 In contrast, our paper is a study of the
effects of taxation on the utilization of labor and capital by firms in differ-
ent locations.
14 Gravelle and Kotlikoff (1989) examine efficiency costs of corporate taxation when
corporate and noncorporate firms produce the same good, finding logically that such
deadweight costs can be substantially higher.
15 Gravelle (2013) demonstrates the sensitivity of these models’ conclusions to modeling
inputs such as factor, product, and capital substitution elasticities.
16 For example, Suarez Serrato and Zidar (2016) use establishment elasticities as an in-
put to their spatial model for calculating incidence.
1270 journal of political economy
Given that our goal is to explain location decisions, a more appropri-
ate conceptual framework for our empirical setting is provided by Dever-
euxandGriffith(1998),basedonHorstmannandMarkusen(1992).Firms
in this model make up to three choices: (1) all choose whether to sell in
the domestic market only or to sell in foreign markets as well; (2) those
firms that choose to sell in foreign markets then choose whether to export
to the foreign market or to set up production in the foreign market (in the
case of services, only the latter would be possible); or (3) conditional on
producing in the foreign market, the firm can choose to produce in any
one of a number of locations.
Devereux and Griffith (2003) build on this model further, highlight-
ing that on the margin of new capital investment, taxes operate through
a conventional cost of capital channel. The level of capital investment is
therefore influenced by the marginal effective tax rate, defined as the
share of the firm’s required return on capital that goes to the federal gov-
ernment rather than to investors (Fullerton 1984). Formally, the marginal
effective tax rate (ETR) is defined as a function of the statutory tax rate t,
the marginal product of capital f 0ðkÞ, the rate of economic depreciation
of capital (d), and the after-tax cost of capital ultimately demanded by in-
vestors (r):
ETR 5
f 0ðkÞ 2 d 2 r
f 0ðkÞ 2 d : (1)
It is usually assumed (as in Hall and Jorgenson [1967]) that firms set the
marginal product of capital equal to the implicit rental value of capital
services:
f 0ðkÞ 5 r 1 dð Þ 1 2 ITC 2 tzð Þ
1 2 t
, (2)
where ITC represents the rate of any investment tax credits, and z repre-
sents the present value of depreciation deductions. Gravelle (1994) and
Gruber and Rauh (2007) calculate marginal effective tax rates by industry
as a function of the specific mix of capital types employed in the produc-
tion process, the estimated rates of economic depreciation of each type
of capital, and the present value of allowable depreciation deductions
for each type of capital.
In the …
Politics/Policy
Companies' Foreign Tax Havens Cost You Plenty
Microsoft, Pfizer, and other businesses avoid U.S. taxes by keeping billions in profits overseas.
Here's what the revenue would add up to, per person, if states and the IRS could get it.
States that would gain
the most per capita
It O Less than$750
0$750-$999
0 $1,000 -$1,249
$1,250 -$1,500
• More than $1,500
Oregon
$1,022
A 2013 state law
requires companies to
report and pay taxes
on profits stashed in
39 overseas havens
Montana
$1126
The first to recover
overseas taxes with a
2003 law that's a model
for other states
school spending, and simple inflation will
tend to cause spending to rise, not fall, in
the years ahead. The question is whether
Brownback will still be in office to try to
keep that from happening. -Peter Coy
The bottom line In Kansas, income growth is
lower than neighboring states' despite-
or because of-steep tax and budget cuts.
Taxes
States Target Corporate
Cash Stashed Overseas
► Laws require companies to pay
state taxes on sheltered profits
► It's "not smart, and not fair" to let
businesses hide money abroad
Members of Congress have complained
for years about U.S. corporations
that park profits overseas to avoid
paying federal taxes. Yet efforts to pass
corporate tax reform that includes
incentives and penalties to prod busi
nesses into bringing that money home
have stalled in Washington. Tired
of waiting for a fix, several states
are going after state tax dollars that
disappear into offshore havens.
Oregon enacted a bill last June for the
2014 tax year identifying 39 countries
and territories-including Barbados,
Liberia, and the U.S. Virgin Islands-
as corporate shelters. The state counts
profits that corporations and their
subsidiaries stash in shelter countries
as taxable income, and companies that
do business in the state must report it
on their state tax returns and pay up.
On April 16 the Democrat-controlled
Maine legislature gave final approval
to similar legislation, over objections
from some Republicans that it's anti
business. Minnesota and Rhode Island
are studying whether to pursue bills of
their own. "The issue at hand is one of
fairness," Maine Representative Adam
Goode, a Democrat from Bangor, said
during the debate on the bill he spon
sored. "It really just seemed not in
balance, not smart, and not fair that
we would allow multinational corpo
rations to hide their corporate income
in a place like the Cayman Islands or
in Bermuda."
Offshore tax shelters cost the
federal government $30 billion to
$90 billion annually, according to a 2013
Congressional Research Service report.
The U.S. Public Interest Research
Group, which tracks corporate taxes,
puts the amount that states lose at
$20 billion a year. The largest U.S.
based multinational companies have
accumulated $1.95 trillion in profits
District of Columbia
$2,783
North Dakota
$2,547
Wyoming
$2,546
Connecticut
$2,537
New York
$1,919
Massachusetts
$1,886
California
$1,783
New Jersey
$1,560
Illinois
$1,396
Colorado
$1,361
DATA: U.S, PIRG
outside the U.S. That's up $206 billion, t
or 11.8 percent, from a year earlier,
according to securities filings from
307 corporations.
Microsoft, Apple, and IBM
accounted for $37-5 billion, or
18.2 percent, of the total increase during
the past year. Caterpillar avoided
$2.4 billion in U.S. taxes over more than
a decade by shifting profits from a parts
business to a subsidiary in Switzerland,
according to a report issued on March 31
by a Senate committee. The company
says the move was legal and appropriate.
"To the extent that they have figured
out ways to avoid paying their proper
share, then it's our job to try to prevent
them," says Oregon State Representative
Phil Barnhart, a Democrat who spon
sored tax-haven legislation there.
The model for the recent legislation
is Montana, which began taxing shel
tered profits a decade ago, followed by
Alaska, West Virginia, and the District
of Columbia. Montana recouped
$7.1 million in taxes in 2010 from com
panies that held money in five top
havens, according to a 2012 state report.
Oregon estimates its new law will allow
it to bring in $18 million a year initially.
Maine projects $5 million in additional
yearly tax revenue if Governor Paul Le
Page, a Republican, signs the bill. (He
hasn't said whether he will.) That's
not much by Washington standards, ►
Read "States Target Corporate Cash Stashed Overseas," by Niquette and Rubin, from Bloomberg
Businessweek (2014).
URL:
https://lopes.idm.oclc.org/login?url=http://search.ebscohost.com.lopes.idm.oclc.org/login.aspx?
direct=true&db=bth&AN=95663541&site=ehost-live&scope=site
Politics/Policy
A but it's a sizable windfall for smaller
states struggling to meet their budgets.
Few of the states that have passed or
are contemplating tax-haven legisla-
tion are home to a large multinational
such as Microsoft, which is based in
Washington, or Apple in California, IBM
in New York, or Caterpillar in Illinois.
Those states would stand to collect far
more from such measures. California
lost the most to offshore havens in 20lt,
an estimated $3.3 billion, the Public
Interest Research Group reports. Ron
Erickson, a former lawmaker who spon-
sored Montana's bill in 2003, expects
more states to start demanding their
share. "I'm discouraged that it's gone
this slowly," he says, "but I'm also
of the confident sort that thinks that
eventually fairness wins out."
—Mark Niquette with Richard Rubin
The bottom line States want their share of
$20 billion in lost tax revenue from companies
that park profits in foreign tax havens.
Tradt
Delta Attempts to Ground
T h e Bank of Boeing'
• The airline demands an end to U.S.
loans to help foreign rivals buy jets
• The Export-Import bank is a
"corporate-welfare slush fund"
This year Congress will debate whether
to renew the charter of the Export-
Import Bank, the 80-year-old federal
institution that helps U.S. compa-
nies sell products and services over-
seas by providing loan guarantees and
otber sweeteners to foreign
buyers. And like the last time
the bank came up for renewal,
in 2012, that debate will reig-
nite a bitter, years-long feud
between two big American
companies: Boeing, which
lobbies furiously to protect the
bank, and Delta Air Lines,
which presses just as hard to
eliminate the bank's finan-
cial aid for foreign buyers of Boeing's
largest jets-who also happen to be
Delta rivals.
The Ex-Im Bank put up $27.3 billion
in 2013 to help small and large U.S.
companies close deals overseas. It
provided a South African company
with $230 million in loan guaran-
tees to buy 100 locomotives built
by General Electric and gave a
$155 million direct loan to the Republic
of Ghana to finance a hospital expan-
sion designed and built by Miami-
based Americaribe. Over the years,
though, no U.S. company has bene-
fited more from the agency's largesse
than Boeing. In 2013, the Ex-Im Bank
offered $7.9 billion in loan guarantees
to help the manufacturer sell 106 of
its airplanes to foreign airlines in two
dozen countries, reinforcing Ex-Im's
Washington nickname-"the Bank
of Boeing."
Delta, a major purchaser of Boeing
jets, says the bank gives an unfair
boost to its overseas competitors. In an
April 7 letter to the House Committee
on Financial Services, Lee Moak, a
Delta captain who's president of the
Air Line Pilots Association, said the
"bank's unnecessary financing of
wide-body aircraft" gives foreign car-
riers an "annual economic advan-
tage" of $2 milfion per aircraft.
'People on both
sides of the
political spectrum
see that
government
should not be
picking winners
and losers."
Senator
Mike Lee
(Boeing disputes this figure.)
Conservative groups and their
allies in Congress have taken
up the cause, saying the bank
isn't needed because foreign
companies can get financ-
ing without the Ex-Im Bank's
help. They also argue it bene-
fits some U.S. companies over
others. "People on both sides
of the political spectrum see
that government should not be picking
winners and losers in business," says
Republican Senator Mike Lee of Utah,
who wants to close the bank. The Club
for Growth calls the Ex-Im Bank a
"corporate-welfare slush fund."
Those are the same words Barack
Obama used to describe it when he
was running against government
breaks for big corporations as a pres-
idential candidate in 2008. He's since
changed his mind and joins most
Democrats in backing the bank and
praising the financial aid that makes
Boeing and other U.S. companies
more attractive to foreign customers.
Boeing President and Chief Operating
Officer Dennis Muilenburg told an
April 3 meeting of the U.S. Chamber
of Commerce-which supports the
Ex-Im Bank-that it's an "important
tool" helping U.S. exporters to better
compete around the world. The
chamber and other backers point out
that Airbus receives generous export
credit assistance from European gov-
ernments. Ending the bank's financ-
ing for large aircraft exports "would
amount to unilateral disarma-
ment," Muilenburg said.
Bank officials say
their loans and guar-
antees cUnch
deals that
Jets vs. Jobs
In 2011 court documents, Delta
Air Lines blamed the Export-Import
Bank for a loss of as many as
7500
U.S. airline jobs, saying foreign airlines
increased their passenger capacity
after buying Boeing jets using Ex-Im
Bank loan guarantees.
E LTA
In Its 2013 annual report, the Ex-Im
Bank countered that its lending
helped companies—including
Boeing—sell billions of dollars worth
of U.S.-made products overseas,
supporting more than
2
U.S.jobs.
• • • • • • • •
• I
Copyright of Bloomberg Businessweek is the property of Bloomberg, L.P. and its content
may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright
holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for
individual use.
CATEGORIES
Economics
Nursing
Applied Sciences
Psychology
Science
Management
Computer Science
Human Resource Management
Accounting
Information Systems
English
Anatomy
Operations Management
Sociology
Literature
Education
Business & Finance
Marketing
Engineering
Statistics
Biology
Political Science
Reading
History
Financial markets
Philosophy
Mathematics
Law
Criminal
Architecture and Design
Government
Social Science
World history
Chemistry
Humanities
Business Finance
Writing
Programming
Telecommunications Engineering
Geography
Physics
Spanish
ach
e. Embedded Entrepreneurship
f. Three Social Entrepreneurship Models
g. Social-Founder Identity
h. Micros-enterprise Development
Outcomes
Subset 2. Indigenous Entrepreneurship Approaches (Outside of Canada)
a. Indigenous Australian Entrepreneurs Exami
Calculus
(people influence of
others) processes that you perceived occurs in this specific Institution Select one of the forms of stratification highlighted (focus on inter the intersectionalities
of these three) to reflect and analyze the potential ways these (
American history
Pharmacology
Ancient history
. Also
Numerical analysis
Environmental science
Electrical Engineering
Precalculus
Physiology
Civil Engineering
Electronic Engineering
ness Horizons
Algebra
Geology
Physical chemistry
nt
When considering both O
lassrooms
Civil
Probability
ions
Identify a specific consumer product that you or your family have used for quite some time. This might be a branded smartphone (if you have used several versions over the years)
or the court to consider in its deliberations. Locard’s exchange principle argues that during the commission of a crime
Chemical Engineering
Ecology
aragraphs (meaning 25 sentences or more). Your assignment may be more than 5 paragraphs but not less.
INSTRUCTIONS:
To access the FNU Online Library for journals and articles you can go the FNU library link here:
https://www.fnu.edu/library/
In order to
n that draws upon the theoretical reading to explain and contextualize the design choices. Be sure to directly quote or paraphrase the reading
ce to the vaccine. Your campaign must educate and inform the audience on the benefits but also create for safe and open dialogue. A key metric of your campaign will be the direct increase in numbers.
Key outcomes: The approach that you take must be clear
Mechanical Engineering
Organic chemistry
Geometry
nment
Topic
You will need to pick one topic for your project (5 pts)
Literature search
You will need to perform a literature search for your topic
Geophysics
you been involved with a company doing a redesign of business processes
Communication on Customer Relations. Discuss how two-way communication on social media channels impacts businesses both positively and negatively. Provide any personal examples from your experience
od pressure and hypertension via a community-wide intervention that targets the problem across the lifespan (i.e. includes all ages).
Develop a community-wide intervention to reduce elevated blood pressure and hypertension in the State of Alabama that in
in body of the report
Conclusions
References (8 References Minimum)
*** Words count = 2000 words.
*** In-Text Citations and References using Harvard style.
*** In Task section I’ve chose (Economic issues in overseas contracting)"
Electromagnetism
w or quality improvement; it was just all part of good nursing care. The goal for quality improvement is to monitor patient outcomes using statistics for comparison to standards of care for different diseases
e a 1 to 2 slide Microsoft PowerPoint presentation on the different models of case management. Include speaker notes... .....Describe three different models of case management.
visual representations of information. They can include numbers
SSAY
ame workbook for all 3 milestones. You do not need to download a new copy for Milestones 2 or 3. When you submit Milestone 3
pages):
Provide a description of an existing intervention in Canada
making the appropriate buying decisions in an ethical and professional manner.
Topic: Purchasing and Technology
You read about blockchain ledger technology. Now do some additional research out on the Internet and share your URL with the rest of the class
be aware of which features their competitors are opting to include so the product development teams can design similar or enhanced features to attract more of the market. The more unique
low (The Top Health Industry Trends to Watch in 2015) to assist you with this discussion.
https://youtu.be/fRym_jyuBc0
Next year the $2.8 trillion U.S. healthcare industry will finally begin to look and feel more like the rest of the business wo
evidence-based primary care curriculum. Throughout your nurse practitioner program
Vignette
Understanding Gender Fluidity
Providing Inclusive Quality Care
Affirming Clinical Encounters
Conclusion
References
Nurse Practitioner Knowledge
Mechanics
and word limit is unit as a guide only.
The assessment may be re-attempted on two further occasions (maximum three attempts in total). All assessments must be resubmitted 3 days within receiving your unsatisfactory grade. You must clearly indicate “Re-su
Trigonometry
Article writing
Other
5. June 29
After the components sending to the manufacturing house
1. In 1972 the Furman v. Georgia case resulted in a decision that would put action into motion. Furman was originally sentenced to death because of a murder he committed in Georgia but the court debated whether or not this was a violation of his 8th amend
One of the first conflicts that would need to be investigated would be whether the human service professional followed the responsibility to client ethical standard. While developing a relationship with client it is important to clarify that if danger or
Ethical behavior is a critical topic in the workplace because the impact of it can make or break a business
No matter which type of health care organization
With a direct sale
During the pandemic
Computers are being used to monitor the spread of outbreaks in different areas of the world and with this record
3. Furman v. Georgia is a U.S Supreme Court case that resolves around the Eighth Amendments ban on cruel and unsual punishment in death penalty cases. The Furman v. Georgia case was based on Furman being convicted of murder in Georgia. Furman was caught i
One major ethical conflict that may arise in my investigation is the Responsibility to Client in both Standard 3 and Standard 4 of the Ethical Standards for Human Service Professionals (2015). Making sure we do not disclose information without consent ev
4. Identify two examples of real world problems that you have observed in your personal
Summary & Evaluation: Reference & 188. Academic Search Ultimate
Ethics
We can mention at least one example of how the violation of ethical standards can be prevented. Many organizations promote ethical self-regulation by creating moral codes to help direct their business activities
*DDB is used for the first three years
For example
The inbound logistics for William Instrument refer to purchase components from various electronic firms. During the purchase process William need to consider the quality and price of the components. In this case
4. A U.S. Supreme Court case known as Furman v. Georgia (1972) is a landmark case that involved Eighth Amendment’s ban of unusual and cruel punishment in death penalty cases (Furman v. Georgia (1972)
With covid coming into place
In my opinion
with
Not necessarily all home buyers are the same! When you choose to work with we buy ugly houses Baltimore & nationwide USA
The ability to view ourselves from an unbiased perspective allows us to critically assess our personal strengths and weaknesses. This is an important step in the process of finding the right resources for our personal learning style. Ego and pride can be
· By Day 1 of this week
While you must form your answers to the questions below from our assigned reading material
CliftonLarsonAllen LLP (2013)
5 The family dynamic is awkward at first since the most outgoing and straight forward person in the family in Linda
Urien
The most important benefit of my statistical analysis would be the accuracy with which I interpret the data. The greatest obstacle
From a similar but larger point of view
4 In order to get the entire family to come back for another session I would suggest coming in on a day the restaurant is not open
When seeking to identify a patient’s health condition
After viewing the you tube videos on prayer
Your paper must be at least two pages in length (not counting the title and reference pages)
The word assimilate is negative to me. I believe everyone should learn about a country that they are going to live in. It doesnt mean that they have to believe that everything in America is better than where they came from. It means that they care enough
Data collection
Single Subject Chris is a social worker in a geriatric case management program located in a midsize Northeastern town. She has an MSW and is part of a team of case managers that likes to continuously improve on its practice. The team is currently using an
I would start off with Linda on repeating her options for the child and going over what she is feeling with each option. I would want to find out what she is afraid of. I would avoid asking her any “why” questions because I want her to be in the here an
Summarize the advantages and disadvantages of using an Internet site as means of collecting data for psychological research (Comp 2.1) 25.0\% Summarization of the advantages and disadvantages of using an Internet site as means of collecting data for psych
Identify the type of research used in a chosen study
Compose a 1
Optics
effect relationship becomes more difficult—as the researcher cannot enact total control of another person even in an experimental environment. Social workers serve clients in highly complex real-world environments. Clients often implement recommended inte
I think knowing more about you will allow you to be able to choose the right resources
Be 4 pages in length
soft MB-920 dumps review and documentation and high-quality listing pdf MB-920 braindumps also recommended and approved by Microsoft experts. The practical test
g
One thing you will need to do in college is learn how to find and use references. References support your ideas. College-level work must be supported by research. You are expected to do that for this paper. You will research
Elaborate on any potential confounds or ethical concerns while participating in the psychological study 20.0\% Elaboration on any potential confounds or ethical concerns while participating in the psychological study is missing. Elaboration on any potenti
3 The first thing I would do in the family’s first session is develop a genogram of the family to get an idea of all the individuals who play a major role in Linda’s life. After establishing where each member is in relation to the family
A Health in All Policies approach
Note: The requirements outlined below correspond to the grading criteria in the scoring guide. At a minimum
Chen
Read Connecting Communities and Complexity: A Case Study in Creating the Conditions for Transformational Change
Read Reflections on Cultural Humility
Read A Basic Guide to ABCD Community Organizing
Use the bolded black section and sub-section titles below to organize your paper. For each section
Losinski forwarded the article on a priority basis to Mary Scott
Losinksi wanted details on use of the ED at CGH. He asked the administrative resident