Intro to economics Discussion module one - Economics
The discussion questions each week will be based on your readings from the online textbook and from Economic Freedom and Human Flourishing.
Select one of the questions below to address. Respond to at least two of your peers, one of which would be a question you did not address. Support your response with at least one source from the course materials. Do additional research if you wish. Include all references and citations in APA format.
Economics is said to be the study of how people make decisions in the face of scarcity in order to maximize their happiness. How would Aristotle respond to this definition?
What assumptions about the economy must be true for the invisible hand to work? To what extent are those assumptions valid in the real world?
*** PLEASE USE ATTACHED RESOURCES***
P E R S P E C T I V E S F R O M P O L I T I C A L P H I LO S O P H Y
ECONOMIC FREEDOM
A N D HUMAN FLOURISHING
A M E R I C A N E N T E R P R I S E I N S T I T U T E
Steven Bilakovics • Richard Boyd • Ryan Patrick Hanley
Peter B. Josephson • Yuval Levin • Harvey C. Mansfield
Deirdre Nansen McCloskey • John T. Scott • Susan Meld Shell
Edited by Michael R. Strain and Stan A. Veuger
P E R S P E C T I V E S F R O M P O L I T I C A L P H I LO S O P H Y
ECONOMIC FREEDOM
A N D HUMAN FLOURISHING
A M E R I C A N E N T E R P R I S E I N S T I T U T E
Steven Bilakovics • Richard Boyd
Ryan Patrick Hanley • Peter B. Josephson
Yuval Levin • Harvey C. Mansfield
Deirdre Nansen McCloskey • John T. Scott
Susan Meld Shell
Edited by Michael R. Strain and Stan A. Veuger
© 2016 by the American Enterprise Institute. All rights reserved.
No part of this publication may be used or reproduced in any man-
ner whatsoever without permission in writing from the American
Enterprise Institute except in the case of brief quotations embodied
in news articles, critical articles, or reviews. The views expressed in
the publications of the American Enterprise Institute are those of the
authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the staff, advisory
panels, officers, or trustees of AEI. The American Enterprise Insti-
tute is a nonpartisan, nonprofit, 501(c)(3) educational organization
and does not take institutional positions on any issues.
American Enterprise Institute
1150 17th St. NW
Washington, DC 20036
www.aei.org
ISBN-13: 978-0-8447-5001-9 (hardback)
ISBN-10: 0-8447-5001-8 (hardback)
ISBN-13: 978-0-8447-5002-6 (paperback)
ISBN-10: 0-8447-5002-6 (paperback)
ISBN-13: 978-0-8447-5003-3 (ebook)
ISBN-10: 0-8447-5003-4 (ebook)
iii
Contents
Preface v
Michael R. Strain and Stan A. Veuger
Aristotle on Economics and the Flourishing Life 1
Harvey C. Mansfield
Hobbes, Locke, and the Problems of Political Economy 9
Peter B. Josephson
Rousseau on Economic Liberty and Human Flourishing 30
John T. Scott
Adam Smith and Human Flourishing 46
Ryan Patrick Hanley
Economic Liberty and Human Flourishing: Kant on
Society, Citizenship, and Redistributive Justice 58
Susan Meld Shell
Edmund Burke’s Economics of Flourishing 84
Yuval Levin
Capitalism as a Road to Serfdom? Tocqueville on
Economic Liberty and Human Flourishing 96
Steven Bilakovics
John Stuart Mill on Economic Liberty and Human
Flourishing 108
Richard Boyd
iv ECONOMIC FREEDOM AND HUMAN FLOURISHING
Economic Liberty as Anti-Flourishing:
Marx and Especially His Followers 129
Deirdre Nansen McCloskey
About the Authors 150
v
Preface
It is easy to forget the broader context in which public policy is placed. So much attention is paid to the means by which policy
is conceived and implemented—politics—that it is easy to focus on
the game and to lose sight of the reason the game exists in the first
place. Conversely, in the world of public policy research, your view
can easily become dominated by minutia: Is a particular elasticity
equal to –0.1 or –0.2? Should a tax credit be capped at $500 per
year or $750?
It is helpful and refreshing to broaden the lens from time to time.
This collection seeks to do that.
Our subject is whether economic liberty is necessary for indi-
viduals to lead truly flourishing lives. This question underlies—or,
at least, it should underlie—many of our most important policy
debates. But it is harder to answer than it may seem. What do we
mean by liberty? What is the flourishing life? And once settled on
definitions, how are the two related?
To answer these questions, we rely on some of history’s great-
est thinkers, interpreted by some of today’s leading scholars of their
thought. Their essays are valuable—it turns out that Aristotle and
Burke and Mill, and philosophers in their class, have much to offer
today’s public debate. And we still have much to learn from Marx’s
mistakes as well.
Politics is important. A deeper understanding of technical ques-
tions of economics and social science are important. Both are critical,
even. But so too is an understanding of why these endeavors matter—
or even exist.
M.R.S. & S.A.V.
Washington, DC
June 2016
1
Aristotle on Economics and
the Flourishing Life
HARVEY C. MANSFIELD
Harvard University and the Hoover Institution
To introduce this large topic, it is fitting to consider Aristotle, for centuries “the master of those who know” (as Dante called
him). By contrast to our thinking, Aristotle wrote comprehensively
on both economics and the flourishing life. Modern economics
makes its way without study of the “flourishing life,” which is one
translation of what Aristotle meant by happiness. For him, as for
common sense, happiness is the goal of ethics and politics, and ulti-
mately of economics. At present, however, economics contents itself
with the “pursuit of happiness” (to borrow from the Declaration of
Independence), a catchall category that specifies at great length how
to pursue but hardly at all what to pursue.
If we follow Aristotle’s method of beginning from what is familiar,
we must begin from modern economics, which is more familiar to
us than Aristotle. Every college student has taken, or should have
taken, Economics 101, and those who have been deprived of this
advantage have to learn what is taught in that course, perhaps more
cheaply, perhaps not, in the School of Hard Knocks. Whether the
study of economics is worth its cost is an example of a typical eco-
nomic calculation, for economics is about calculation. A calculation
is a deliberation that focuses on a number, a “metric,” of more, of a
greater quantity. It avoids the question of how much more is needed
before one can decide that one can stop acquiring and turn to enjoy-
ment. Originally—and this is in Aristotle as well as in the founders of
modern economics—economics supposed that it could define needs
2 ECONOMIC FREEDOM AND HUMAN FLOURISHING
or necessities as opposed to surplus or superfluities. But necessities
have a way of expanding from survival to comfort and from comfort
to perfect assurance, so that it seems safer, and scientifically more
exact, to consider them infinite and thus decline to define them.
Economics becomes the science of getting more without ever
saying how much more. It is because of its exactness that science
requires this vagueness. Economics must either be exact or fall silent;
it disdains and rejects the possibility of an inexact statement that is
merely probable and better than nothing. It may attempt to evade
the difficulty by defining “probability” exactly. The result would be
either a vague definition of exact or an exact definition of vague—
which leaves the common sense “probable” in charge. So the science
of more, of “growth,” drops the utilitarian posture that requires a
definition of utility—possibly contestable—and turns to “prefer-
ences” that are admittedly quite subjective. Thus does the objectivity
of economics require that it surrender totally to human subjectivity.
And as the measuring of preferences becomes increasingly sophisti-
cated, which means increasingly mathematical, economics becomes
increasingly vague as to its end and continually further from defining
the “flourishing life.”
At the same time the boundary of economics becomes increas-
ingly uncertain. It used to be that economists, when pressured with a
question hard to answer, would frequently resort to a boundary state-
ment and say: “That’s a noneconomic question.” That distinguished
an economist from a political scientist, who could never say “that’s a
nonpolitical question” because politics admits no sanctuary from pol-
itics. But now economists have invaded political science, for example
with game theory, reducing political questions to economic ones, and
with the same increasing exactness that promotes increasing vague-
ness. It is true that many political scientists today, as distinguished
from Aristotle, welcome these invaders as saviors of their science.
The discussion so far has a skeptical tone you will not find in
Economics 101. But perhaps economics does have, despite its sci-
entific pretensions, an end in view—and thus a contribution to the
question of what is happiness. My father, a professor, used to rent
his house in the summer to other professors who needed to live in
ARISTOTLE 3
the city he wanted to leave. This was an economic transaction. But
he soon learned from hard experience that it was far preferable to
rent to an economist than to a sociologist. His lesson was that econ-
omists believe in bourgeois virtue and sociologists do not. This is
not a matter of calculation but of difference of habit, even of way of
life, that he observed. Or it was calculation over the long term, never
actually tested, that unkept promises and slovenly behavior would
eventually be punished in this world: this is calculation not much
different from virtue.
A problem of how to live can be seen within economic calcula-
tion. Which is better, to spend or to save? In the recent economic
crisis, the American government passed a “stimulus” bill, meaning a
stimulus on the consumer to spend. But it could also be said that in
difficult times it is better to save—as many people did, not respond-
ing to the stimulus. Economic calculation might say that it is bet-
ter sometimes to save, sometimes to spend, that to be rational one
should have no predisposition for one or the other. But to spend or
to save is a life choice; each way has habits of its own that are hard
to change quickly in accordance with calculation, as when buying
or selling a stock. A calculator is always ready to adjust and finds
habit, which is fixed and not calculated, to be irrational (as in a way
it is). Here, within economic rationality, we see two opposing ways
of life, two opposite souls, the easy spender and the tightwad, both
economic, but not determined solely by economic advantage.
Turning to Aristotle, we see him considering ways of life with a
view to which is best rather than calculation of what brings in more.
More what, he wants to know, and how much more? For him the
“pursuit” of happiness implies an end to the pursuit, since endless
pursuit is futile and irrational. All human beings pursue happiness;
everything else is instrumental to happiness and pursued because
it brings happiness. Even virtue, though an end in itself and often
involving sacrifice, is also pursued as the means to happiness. Vir-
tue won’t, or at least shouldn’t, make you miserable, Aristotle says,
somewhat optimistically. To be happy is to be at rest, as we say, “sit-
ting pretty.” Those who scramble without end don’t know how to
stop, don’t know how to enjoy. “Enjoy!” we say today in moments
4 ECONOMIC FREEDOM AND HUMAN FLOURISHING
of respite; Aristotle would say that enjoyment (not relaxation) is
the whole purpose of scrambling to get ahead. Relaxation is to gain
respite from scrambling so that one can resume it refreshed, but
enjoyment is satisfaction in an end attained.
The art or science of achieving happiness is political, and Aristotle
calls politics the “master science,” the one that orders and rules over
all other sciences, arts, and practices in a society. Even a free society
is ruled in such a way that its parts are free and contribute to the
whole of a free society. The “free market” studied and recommended
by economics has to be the result of a political decision to establish
and maintain it. In general, only politics can restrain politics. The
free market needs to be sustained by “bourgeois virtue” taught in the
schools and the family in consequence of a fundamentally political
decision to lead a certain way of life and to live by its rules. The
indispensable lessons of Economics 101 also need to be taught by
the permission and favor of politics. What we call “civil society” sim-
ilarly needs the good opinion and sponsorship of our rulers. Under
the notion of “rule” Aristotle puts the main principles or principle of
every way of life, so that politics promotes a definition of happiness,
not just the means to undefined happiness. “Pluralism” in a society
establishes a pluralistic society, a certain type of society distinctive
in its ways from other, more prescriptive societies that it rejects and
excludes. Aristotle’s “master science” provides a comprehensive role
for politics, but it should not be confused with a program for Big
Government.
Reading from Aristotle’s Ethics as well as his Politics, we see he
maintains that virtue is the core of happiness. He means this in both
a normative and a descriptive sense. Descriptively, every society has
a virtue or cluster of virtues that it promotes as characterizing its way
of life and defining its notion of happiness, often in his day the virtue
of courage or martial spirit. But as every society claims that its prized
virtue is best, Aristotle feels bound to judge normatively whether
this claim is correct. For him there is no unbridgeable distinction
between fact and value.
Now it is obvious that virtue cannot assure happiness. This is
true not so much because we often witness the sad fact of virtue
ARISTOTLE 5
unrewarded—for virtue is its own reward (not always sufficient!)—
but because we observe virtue thwarted for lack of means. Virtue
stands in need of “equipment,” Aristotle says nicely. It needs good
fortune or the gods’ blessing (implied in the Greek word for hap-
piness, eudaimonia, well-blessed), and it needs wealth. One cannot
be generous without wealth to give away. Here enters the need for
economics as akin to a science of wealth-getting but distinct from it
because economics needs to be limited. Aristotle does not hold to
the purity of virtue understood as bringing no personal advantage
(called “altruism”), but he does agree that wealth-getting is mor-
ally dangerous. It is essentially instrumental to virtue but can often
become an end in itself regardless of virtue, Aristotle here in accord
with Karl Marx. Money monetizes everything, as with the touch of
King Midas, and thereby seems to dissolve all value except itself.
Virtue as the core of happiness is a habit, not a calculation. If you
have to calculate the advantage from virtue, you are no longer being
virtuous for the sake of virtue, which is no longer virtuous. You are
merely behaving virtuously while others are watching, which is not
enough. Virtue is in the intent as well as in the action. Yet again
Aristotle admits that calculation can enter into virtue, for example,
a generous person calculating how much to give or a courageous
person reasoning in a situation of combat so as to avoid being rash.
Virtue is divided into virtues, of which Aristotle names 11. An indi-
vidual can practice one virtue without the others, and although it
is desirable to have all the virtues, and Aristotle adds, to know you
have them, this is rare.
Like individuals, societies (or, since “society” is a modern con-
struct, political regimes, politeiai) tend to specialize in certain virtues.
Indeed, regimes are necessarily biased in a certain direction, whereas
a rare individual might have all the virtues. Regimes have laws that
enshrine their characteristic virtues and make it difficult to adjust
to new situations as they might do if they were more calculating.
Most men and hence all peoples, because they have a character or
type, resist change until they are compelled to change, and then they
adopt and hold to the new regime. One revolution leads in time to
another, not to an end of revolution—even though all revolution
6 ECONOMIC FREEDOM AND HUMAN FLOURISHING
aims at being the final revolution. In the long view politics must rec-
ognize the limits to what can be achieved by politics, which means
by human beings. The indefinite or infinite growth that modern eco-
nomics dimly imagines as its goal is not viable, even if “growth” into
nothing definite were intelligible as mere expansion. The same goes
for the modern notion of progress or perfectibility, which today has
dissolved into “change,” as if it were possible for change to occur
except with respect to something that does not change. For if “Amer-
ica has changed totally,” how could you still call it “America”?
Within Aristotelian virtue there is a distinction characteristic of
the Socratic tradition and very important for both economics and
flourishing life. This is between the just and the noble. The just is
what can be expected from citizens, one’s duty or obligation; it con-
tains an element of compulsion although it is voluntary like all the
virtues. Examples are paying one’s taxes or bills; payment is virtuous
but expected and therefore not admired. Noble actions, however, go
“beyond the call of duty,” as we still say; they contain an element of
risk and might earn a medal. Modern morality dating from Thomas
Hobbes wants to avoid this distinction and to make all morality
more certain by considering all of it (typically) under the concept of
justice as virtue to be expected. This move permits all morality to be
more predictable and calculable, less subject to chance. Happiness
in a flourishing life may be more attractive, more admirable, as in
the classical gentleman, but homo economicus—the morality of man
subject to the laws of economics—is more regular and dependable.
The morality of the modern economic man can be calculated
together with his economic behavior. In this calculation another
distinction within Aristotelian virtue between intellectual and moral
virtue can be overcome and the two combined. In the modern view,
moral virtue comes under the rule of theory instead of being distinct
from it. Moral theory takes the place of ordinary, unscientific praise
and blame, and modern philosophers no longer make a point of
rising above morality but stoop down to take charge of it. Happiness
is regularized by being reduced to something less than the flourish-
ing life of a gentleman or lady, let alone a philosopher—to a more
attainable life such as bourgeois virtue. Bourgeois virtue has not
ARISTOTLE 7
been an unqualified success, however. It turns out that the morality
that is more easily attained is also less satisfying, less interesting. A
new concern for the boredom of bourgeois society arises, and ennui
becomes the problem. Sociology with its critique of bourgeois hap-
piness is born. Modern man would rather be “inner-directed” toward
self-expression than calculate his self-interest in conformity with
society’s norms. A version or perversion of ancient nobility comes to
life again in the guise of the radical and the hippy, who in their sepa-
rate lives concur to disdain the pettiness of bourgeois virtue.
Of the two parts of Aristotle’s virtue, the noble is more a problem
for economics. The noble makes us resist economic advantage and
the insistence of “incentives” (another modern concept). We often
refuse what is presented to us as necessity when necessity no longer
seems truly necessary. Economics expands necessity from minimum
survival to the necessity of seeking a return on one’s money. The rich
man cannot afford not to exploit the opportunities he sees. The poor
and their advocates will question this sort of “necessity.” Also, what
makes virtue noble is doing it for its own sake rather than for your
private advantage. Yet Aristotle, still eschewing moral purity, says
that virtue is for your advantage as well. Virtue makes you a better
person, and perhaps a still better person if you realize that your vir-
tue makes you better. For virtue is enhanced when aware of itself
as the best kind of enjoyment. Similarly, the virtuous person does
not seek pleasure, but he gets pleasure as a by-product of his virtue,
taking a moderate pleasure in doing good and avoiding too much
self-congratulation or superiority.
What is a better person? It is one with a better soul. Aristotle’s
moral, political, and economic thought is based on the soul. In the
best case the soul is well-ordered and harmonious, but in every case
the soul is a human being’s individual self-government. The soul
enables the individual to act and to reflect for himself, as opposed
to the various determinants by which we are known and controlled
by the various modern sciences, all of them denying or overlooking
the soul. Hovering over us today, these sciences want to run our
lives for us through the laws peculiar to each of them: laws of psy-
chology, biology, chemistry, neurology, and—not least—economics.
8 ECONOMIC FREEDOM AND HUMAN FLOURISHING
Much of today’s political science, soulless but not selfless, tries to
imitate these more pretentious and more successful sciences. The
soul, which Aristotle studied so well, stands in the way of these types
of enslavement. It represents freedom in its various aspects: the free-
dom to resist necessity and nature (a freedom given to us by nature),
the freedom to initiate action, the freedom to stop and reflect, the
freedom to take satisfaction in oneself, and the freedom to blame
oneself and feel shame. Human beings with souls fall in love and feel
anger—two types of action that a calculating person never does and
that the calculating sciences never know of.
We need a return to reason, to Aristotelian reason. The reason of
economics is not empirical as it claims. It is based on the dubious
presumption that human beings suffer in a condition of scarcity or
necessity that will oblige them with their “preferences” (really, their
necessities) to choose in ways that economists can predict and then
control. This sort of reason begins in a dubious presumption that
denies human freedom, and it dissolves, we have seen, in vagueness
that fails to specify a reasonable goal of human life. Aristotle’s reason,
by contrast, admits human necessities, for he was one of the found-
ers of economics. But, because it is more empirical than economics
by itself on the basis of human experience, it also seeks, through the
soul, to come to terms with human nobility and freedom. Aristotle’s
reason does its best to define the flourishing life, at its peak as well
as in average, and measure the ordinary and the common by what
is best and rare.
9
Hobbes, Locke, and the Problems
of Political Economy
PETER B. JOSEPHSON
Saint Anselm College
In our own time and place we hotly contest the relation of public and private goods or interests. Education, health and birth con-
trol, energy and the environment, transportation, social welfare—
almost any domestic issue is the subject of such debate. Those
debates typically contest whether the issue at hand is properly a
matter of public policy at all, and if it is, whether the best approach
to addressing the concern is through public or private action. The
contest over what is properly a public concern and what is properly
private, and therefore over the extent of government authority and
the defense of personal responsibility and liberty, has a long history
in America. It is a legacy from our founding and from the intellec-
tual origins of the founding. Those original intellects often thought
better about these enduring problems than we typically do today.
Thus we can better understand our own debate by considering its
intellectual roots in the revolutionary political theories of 17th cen-
tury England, and the understanding in that time and place of the
proper relation of public and private goods.
We will not find an easy resolution of our problem in those theo-
ries. The problem of the relation of public and private goods, like the
problem of the relation of the community to the individual, is one
of the fundamental problems of political justice. It is the problem
that philosophers and statesmen have grappled with for more than
two millennia. But modern thinkers such as Thomas Hobbes and
John Locke place the problem in stark relief, as an issue of political
10 ECONOMIC FREEDOM AND HUMAN FLOURISHING
economy, and the contrasts (and similarities) between them help
us see more precisely the difficulty we face.1 Together, Hobbes and
Locke can lead partisans of both sides to a better appreciation of the
partiality of their positions and a better understanding of the claims
on the other side. For all their differences, Hobbes and Locke recog-
nize that there is no simple identity of public and private interests
or rights.
Hobbes and Locke are often paired. Both are 17th-century English
philosophers (though separated by a generation). Both are state-of-
nature theorists who articulate teachings of natural equality and
natural liberty, and both describe civil society and government as
artifacts of human invention.
The two are also very often contrasted (and their differences
regarding the origin of private property are among the most signif-
icant).2 Yet what we often take to be their differences—the bumper
sticker description of their differences—actually obscures their
teachings and makes each less interesting than he really is. For exam-
ple, both Hobbes and Locke give an account of a state of nature—a
pre-political condition, perhaps meant anthropologically (an his-
torical epoch in a long ago age), or perhaps a hypothetical condi-
tion (what human life would be like without government). Hobbes
famously explains that in the state of nature there is no “mine and
thine,” and “no place for industry, because the fruit thereof is uncer-
tain, and consequently, no culture of the earth . . . no commodious
building . . . no knowledge of the face of the earth.”3 In Hobbes’
account, the condition of perfect liberty and equality—our natu-
ral, ungoverned condition—is a state of war: a war of all against
all that produces a condition that is “solitary, poor, nasty, brutish,
and short.”4 On the other hand, Locke describes a state of nature
that includes natural rights to property and therefore an account of
natural justice. Locke carefully distinguishes the state of nature from
the state of war and describes the state of nature initially as a state of
“perfect freedom” and “equality,” governed by a “law of nature” that
teaches anyone “who will but consult it” that “no one ought to harm
another.”5 In describing the “plain difference” between the state of
nature and a state of war, Locke writes that they are “as far distant,
HOBBES, LOCKE 11
as a State of Peace, Good Will, Mutual Assistance, and Preservation,
and a State of Enmity, Malice, Violence, and Mutual Destruction are
from one another.”6
So Hobbes and Locke seem quite different in their accounts of
our natural condition, and this leads them to address very different
problems. Hobbes is concerned about our natural inclination toward
chaos and war, and must explain how peace is produced. For Hobbes,
the maintenance of public order is an absolute necessity and requires
a nearly absolute sovereign. Locke, beginning more peaceably, must
explain that his state of nature is subject to certain “inconveniences”
that degenerate into war. But this means that Locke can conceive of
a condition without politics that is, at least, livable. The maintenance
of public order is, in Locke’s language, a “convenience,” and in his
Second Treatise Locke uses the word “sovereignty” only twice.7
Hobbes and Locke therefore differ in their accounts of the politics
that emerge out of this natural condition. To address the problem of
the state of war—the state of natural confusion or chaos—Hobbes
counsels that every state must claim, and be granted, absolute sov-
ereign power, and indeed that we are simply fooling ourselves if we
believe politics works in any other way. Anything less than acknowl-
edging the absolute authority of the sovereign—say, if we were to
declare allegiance to the sovereign in some cases but to God in
others—can only breed dissent and ultimately civil war.8 On the
other hand, Locke famously argues that government must be
founded on the consent of the governed, and that political power
should be organized constitutionally into something like a system
of separation of powers and checks and balances. Where Hobbes
emphasizes the authority of the sovereign, Locke emphasizes the
pre-eminence of a legislative power. Locke’s two references to “sov-
ereignty” in the Second Treatise are first as an example of a thing God
has not granted to any person, and second to explain that only God
is sovereign.9
And yet Hobbes’ political account …
Economics in One Lesson
Title Page
Table of Contents
Preface
The Lesson
The Lesson Applied
The Broken Window
The Blessings of Destruction
Public Works Mean Taxes
Taxes Discourage Production
Credit Diverts Production
The Curse of Machinery
Spread-the-Work Schemes
Disbanding Troops and Bureaucrats
The Fetish of Full Employment
Who's "Protected" by Tariffs?
The Drive for Exports
"Parity" Prices
Saving the X Industry
How the Price System Works
"Stabilizing" Commodities
Government Price-Fixing
Minimum Wage Laws
Do Unions Really Raise Wages?
"Enough to Buy Back the Product
The Function of Profits
The Mirage of Inflation
The Assault on Saving
The Lesson Restated
A Note on Books
iNTRO TO ECONOMICS RESOURCES MODULE 1
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=EBifN69gcKY&t=6s
https://youtu.be/JaKMimJPxyA
https://youtu.be/O6XL__2CDPU
https://youtu.be/_7VHfuWV-Qg
(BOOK IS ATTACHED FOR CHAPTER 1 AND 2)
· BBUS 2203 Principles of Microeconomics 2e.8 Chapter 1, "Welcome to Economics”
· BBUS 2203 Principles of Microeconomics 2e.8 Chapter 2, "Choice in a World of Scarcity”
PAGES 1-8
· Economic Freedom and Human Flourishing, Preface and pp. 1-8
· Economics in One Lesson, Preface and Chapter 1
PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS
Chapter 1 Welcome to Economics!
PowerPoint Image Slideshow
FIGURE 1.1
Economics is greatly impacted by how well information travels through society. Today,
social media giants Twitter, Facebook, and Instagram are major forces on the
information super highway. (Credit: modification of work by Manuel Iglesias/Flickr
Creative Commons)
FIGURE 1.2
Homeless people are a stark reminder that scarcity of resources is real. (Credit:
“daveynin”/Flickr Creative Commons)
FIGURE 1.3
Adam Smith introduced the idea of
dividing labor into discrete tasks. (Credit:
Wikimedia Commons)
FIGURE 1.4
Workers on an assembly line are an example of the divisions of labor. (Credit: Nina
Hale/Flickr Creative Commons)
FIGURE 1.5
One of the most influential economists in
modern times was John Maynard
Keynes. (Credit: Wikimedia Commons)
FIGURE 1.6
The circular flow diagram shows how households and firms interact in the goods and
services market, and in the labor market. The direction of the arrows shows that in the
goods and services market, households receive goods and services and pay firms for
them. In the labor market, households provide labor and receive payment from firms
through wages, salaries, and benefits.
FIGURE 1.7
Ancient Egypt was an example of a command economy. (Credit: Jay Bergesen/Flickr
Creative Commons)
FIGURE 1.8
Nothing says “market” more than The
New York Stock Exchange. (Credit: Erik
Drost/Flickr Creative Commons)
FIGURE 1.9
Cargo ships are one mode of transportation for shipping goods in the global economy.
(Credit: Raul Valdez/Flickr Creative Commons)
This PowerPoint file is copyright 2011-2015, Rice University. All
Rights Reserved.
PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS
Chapter 2 Choice in a World of Scarcity
PowerPoint Image Slideshow
FIGURE 2.1
In general, the higher the degree, the higher the salary. So why aren’t more people
pursuing higher degrees? The short answer: choices and tradeoffs. (Credit:
modification of work by “Jim, the Photographer”/Flickr Creative Commons)
FIGURE 2.2
Each point on the budget constraint represents a combination of burgers and bus
tickets whose total cost adds up to Alphonso’s budget of $10. The slope of the budget
constraint is determined by the relative price of burgers and bus tickets. All along the
budget set, giving up one burger means gaining four bus tickets.
FIGURE 2.3
This production possibilities frontier shows a tradeoff between devoting social
resources to healthcare and devoting them to education. At A all resources go to
healthcare and at B, most go to healthcare. At D most resources go to education, and
at F, all go to education.
FIGURE 2.4
Productive efficiency means it is impossible to produce more of one good without
decreasing the quantity that is produced of another good. Thus, all choices along a
given PPF like B, C, and D display productive efficiency, but R does not. Allocative
efficiency means that the particular mix of goods being produced—that is, the specific
choice along the production possibilities frontier—represents the allocation that society
most desires.
FIGURE 2.5
The U.S. PPF is flatter than the Brazil PPF implying that the opportunity cost of wheat
in term of sugar cane is lower in the U.S. than in Brazil. Conversely, the opportunity
cost of sugar cane is lower in Brazil. The U.S. has comparative advantage in wheat and
brazil has comparative advantage in sugar cane.
FIGURE 2.6
Both the individual opportunity set (or budget constraint) and the social production
possibilities frontier show the constraints under which individual consumers and society
as a whole operate. Both diagrams show the tradeoff in choosing more of one good at
the cost of less of the other.
This PowerPoint file is copyright 2011-2015, Rice University. All
Rights Reserved.
PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS
Appendix A
PowerPoint Image Slideshow
FIGURE A1
This line graph has x on the horizontal axis and y on the vertical axis. The y-intercept—
that is, the point where the line intersects the y-axis—is 9. The slope of the line is 3;
that is, there is a rise of 3 on the vertical axis for every increase of 1 on the horizontal
axis. The slope is the same all along a straight line.
FIGURE A2
The equations for Qd and Qs are displayed graphically by the sloped lines.
FIGURE A3
The line graph shows the relationship between height and weight for boys and girls
from birth to 3 years. Point A, for example, shows that a boy of 28 inches in height
(measured on the horizontal axis) is typically 19 pounds in weight (measured on the
vertical axis). These data apply only to children in the first three years of life.
FIGURE A4
This line graph shows the relationship between altitude, measured in meters above sea
level, and air density, measured in kilograms of air per cubic meter. As altitude rises, air
density declines. The point at the top of Mount Everest has an altitude of approximately
8,828 meters above sea level (the horizontal axis) and air density of 0.023 kilograms
per cubic meter (the vertical axis).
FIGURE A5
This graph provides a quick visual summary of unemployment data. With a graph like
this, it is easy to spot the times of high unemployment and of low unemployment.
FIGURE A6
The three pie graphs illustrate the division of total population into three age groups for
the three different years.
FIGURE A7
The graph shows the 12 countries of the world with the largest populations. The height
of the bars in the bar graph shows the size of the population for each country.
FIGURE A8
Population data can be represented in different ways.
(a) Shows three bars for each year, representing the total number of persons in each age bracket
for each year.
(b) Shows just one bar for each year, but the different age groups are now shaded inside the bar.
(c) Sets the vertical axis as a measure of percentages rather than the number of persons. All three
bar graphs are the same height and each bar is divided according to the percentage of
population in each age group.
FIGURE A9
FIGURE A10
FIGURE A11
PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS
Appendix B
PowerPoint Image Slideshow
FIGURE B1
Lilly would receive equal utility from all points on a given indifference curve. Any points
on the highest indifference curve Uh, like F, provide greater utility than any points like A,
B, C, and D on the middle indifference curve Um. Similarly, any points on the middle
indifference curve Um provide greater utility than any points on the lowest indifference
curve Ul.
FIGURE B2
Lilly’s preferences are shown by the indifference curves. Lilly’s budget constraint, given
the prices of books and doughnuts and her income, is shown by the straight line. Lilly’s
optimal choice will be point B, where the budget line is tangent to the indifference curve
Um. Lilly would have more utility at a point like F on the higher indifference curve Uh, but
the budget line does not touch the higher indifference curve Uh at any point, so she
cannot afford this choice. A choice like G is affordable to Lilly, but it lies on indifference
curve Ul and thus provides less utility than choice B, which is on indifference curve Um.
FIGURE B3
Manuel and Natasha originally face the same budget constraints; that is, same prices and same income.
However, the indifference curves that illustrate their preferences are not the same.
(a) Manuel’s original choice at W involves more yogurt and more movies, and he reacts to the higher
income by mainly increasing consumption of movies at X.
(b) Conversely, Natasha’s original choice (Y) involves relatively more movies, but she reacts to the higher
income by choosing relatively more yogurts. Even when budget constraints are the same, personal
preferences lead to different original choices and to different reactions in response to a change in
income.
FIGURE B4
The original choice is A, the point of tangency between the original budget constraint and indifference curve.
The new choice is B, the point of tangency between the new budget constraint and the lower indifference curve.
Point C is the tangency between the dashed line, where the slope shows the new higher price of haircuts, and
the original indifference curve. The substitution effect is the shift from A to C, which means getting fewer
haircuts and more pizza. The income effect is the shift from C to B; that is, the reduction in buying power that
causes a shift from the higher indifference curve to the lower indifference curve, with relative prices remaining
unchanged. The income effect results in less consumed of both goods. Both substitution and income effects
cause fewer haircuts to be consumed. For pizza, in this case, the substitution effect and income effect cancel
out, leading to the same amount of pizza consumed.
FIGURE B5
Petunia starts at choice A, the tangency between her original budget constraint and the lower indifference
curve Ul. The wage increase shifts her budget constraint to the right, so that she can now choose B on
indifference curve Uh. The substitution effect is the movement from A to C. In this case, the substitution
effect would lead Petunia to choose less leisure, which is relatively more expensive, and more income,
which is relatively cheaper to earn. The income effect is the movement from C to B. The income effect in this
example leads to greater consumption of both goods. Overall, in this example, income rises because of both
substitution and income effects. However, leisure declines because of the substitution effect but increases
because of the income effect—leading, in Petunia’s case, to an overall increase in the quantity of leisure
consumed.
FIGURE B6
The original choice is A, at the tangency between the original budget constraint and the original indifference curve Uh.
The dashed line is drawn parallel to the new budget set, so that its slope reflects the lower rate of return, but is tangent
to the original indifference curve. The movement from A to C is the substitution effect: in this case, future consumption
has become relatively more expensive, and present consumption has become relatively cheaper. The income effect is
the shift from C to B; that is, the reduction in utility or “buying power” that causes a move to a lower indifference curve
Ul, but with the relative price the same. It means less present and less future consumption. In the move from A to B,
the substitution effect on present consumption is greater than the income effect, so the overall result is more present
consumption. Notice that the lower indifference curve could have been drawn tangent to the lower budget constraint
point D or point F, depending on personal preferences.
FIGURE B7
FIGURE B8
FIGURE B9
FIGURE B10
FIGURE B11
This PowerPoint file is copyright 2011-2015, Rice University. All
Rights Reserved.
Principles of
Microeconomics 2e
SENIOR CONTRIBUTING AUTHORS
STEVEN A. GREENLAW, UNIVERSITY OF MARY WASHINGTON
DAVID SHAPIRO, PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIVERSITY
TIMOTHY TAYLOR, MACALESTER COLLEGE
OpenStax
Rice University
6100 Main Street MS-375
Houston, Texas 77005
To learn more about OpenStax, visit https://openstax.org.
Individual print copies and bulk orders can be purchased through our website.
©2018 Rice University. Textbook content produced by OpenStax is licensed under a Creative Commons
Attribution 4.0 International License (CC BY 4.0). Under this license, any user of this textbook or the textbook
contents herein must provide proper attribution as follows:
- If you redistribute this textbook in a digital format (including but not limited to PDF and HTML), then you
must retain on every page the following attribution:
“Download for free at https://openstax.org/details/books/principles-microeconomics-2e.”
- If you redistribute this textbook in a print format, then you must include on every physical page the
following attribution:
“Download for free at https://openstax.org/details/books/principles-microeconomics-2e.”
- If you redistribute part of this textbook, then you must retain in every digital format page view (including
but not limited to PDF and HTML) and on every physical printed page the following attribution:
“Download for free at https://openstax.org/details/books/principles-microeconomics-2e.”
- If you use this textbook as a bibliographic reference, please include
https://openstax.org/details/books/principles-microeconomics-2e in your citation.
For questions regarding this licensing, please contact [email protected]
Trademarks
The OpenStax name, OpenStax logo, OpenStax book covers, OpenStax CNX name, OpenStax CNX logo,
OpenStax Tutor name, Openstax Tutor logo, Connexions name, Connexions logo, Rice University name, and
Rice University logo are not subject to the license and may not be reproduced without the prior and express
written consent of Rice University.
Portions of the Demand and Supply chapter were derived from "Why It Matters: Government in Action by
Steve Greenlaw and Lumen Learning." Located at:
https://courses.lumenlearning.com/waymakermacroxmasterfall2016/chapter/why-it-matters-government-
action/. License: CC BY 4.0.
PRINT BOOK ISBN-10 1-947172-34-4
PRINT BOOK ISBN-13 978-1-947172-34-0
PDF VERSION ISBN-10 1-947172-35-2
PDF VERSION ISBN-13 978-1-947172-35-7
ENHANCED TEXTBOOK ISBN-10 1-947172-49-2
ENHANCED TEXTBOOK ISBN-13 978-1-947172-49-4
Revision Number ME2-2017-001-(03/18)-LC
Original Publication Year 2017
OPENSTAX
OpenStax provides free, peer-reviewed, openly licensed textbooks for introductory college and Advanced Placement®
courses and low-cost, personalized courseware that helps students learn. A nonprofit ed tech initiative based at Rice
University, we’re committed to helping students access the tools they need to complete their courses and meet their
educational goals.
RICE UNIVERSITY
OpenStax, OpenStax CNX, and OpenStax Tutor are initiatives of Rice University. As a leading research university with a
distinctive commitment to undergraduate education, Rice University aspires to path-breaking research, unsurpassed
teaching, and contributions to the betterment of our world. It seeks to fulfill this mission by cultivating a diverse community
of learning and discovery that produces leaders across the spectrum of human endeavor.
FOUNDATION SUPPORT
OpenStax is grateful for the tremendous support of our sponsors. Without their strong engagement, the goal
of free access to high-quality textbooks would remain just a dream.
Laura and John Arnold Foundation (LJAF) actively seeks opportunities to invest in organizations and
thought leaders that have a sincere interest in implementing fundamental changes that not only
yield immediate gains, but also repair broken systems for future generations. LJAF currently focuses
its strategic investments on education, criminal justice, research integrity, and public accountability.
The William and Flora Hewlett Foundation has been making grants since 1967 to help solve social
and environmental problems at home and around the world. The Foundation concentrates its
resources on activities in education, the environment, global development and population,
performing arts, and philanthropy, and makes grants to support disadvantaged communities in the
San Francisco Bay Area.
Calvin K. Kazanjian was the founder and president of Peter Paul (Almond Joy), Inc. He firmly believed
that the more people understood about basic economics the happier and more prosperous they
would be. Accordingly, he established the Calvin K. Kazanjian Economics Foundation Inc, in 1949 as a
philanthropic, nonpolitical educational organization to support efforts that enhanced economic
understanding.
Guided by the belief that every life has equal value, the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation works to
help all people lead healthy, productive lives. In developing countries, it focuses on improving
people’s health with vaccines and other life-saving tools and giving them the chance to lift
themselves out of hunger and extreme poverty. In the United States, it seeks to significantly
improve education so that all young people have the opportunity to reach their full potential. Based
in Seattle, Washington, the foundation is led by CEO Jeff Raikes and Co-chair William H. Gates Sr.,
under the direction of Bill and Melinda Gates and Warren Buffett.
The Maxfield Foundation supports projects with potential for high impact in science, education,
sustainability, and other areas of social importance.
Our mission at The Michelson 20MM Foundation is to grow access and success by eliminating
unnecessary hurdles to affordability. We support the creation, sharing, and proliferation of more
effective, more affordable educational content by leveraging disruptive technologies, open
educational resources, and new models for collaboration between for-profit, nonprofit, and public
entities.
The Bill and Stephanie Sick Fund supports innovative projects in the areas of Education, Art, Science
and Engineering.
Access. The future of education.
OpenStax.org
I like free textbooks
and I cannot lie.
Give $5 or more
to OpenStax and
we’ll send you a
sticker!
OpenStax is a nonprofit initiative,
which means that that every dollar
you give helps us maintain and grow
our library of free textbooks.
If you have a few dollars to spare,
visit OpenStax.org/give to donate.
We’ll send you an OpenStax sticker
to thank you for your support!
Table of Contents
Preface . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
Chapter 1: Welcome to Economics! . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
1.1 What Is Economics, and Why Is It Important? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
1.2 Microeconomics and Macroeconomics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
1.3 How Economists Use Theories and Models to Understand Economic Issues . . . . . . . . . . 15
1.4 How To Organize Economies: An Overview of Economic Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Chapter 2: Choice in a World of Scarcity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
2.1 How Individuals Make Choices Based on Their Budget Constraint . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
2.2 The Production Possibilities Frontier and Social Choices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.3 Confronting Objections to the Economic Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38
Chapter 3: Demand and Supply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45
3.1 Demand, Supply, and Equilibrium in Markets for Goods and Services . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
3.2 Shifts in Demand and Supply for Goods and Services . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
3.3 Changes in Equilibrium Price and Quantity: The Four-Step Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
3.4 Price Ceilings and Price Floors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67
3.5 Demand, Supply, and Efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71
Chapter 4: Labor and Financial Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83
4.1 Demand and Supply at Work in Labor Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84
4.2 Demand and Supply in Financial Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92
4.3 The Market System as an Efficient Mechanism for Information . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98
Chapter 5: Elasticity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107
5.1 Price Elasticity of Demand and Price Elasticity of Supply . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108
5.2 Polar Cases of Elasticity and Constant Elasticity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113
5.3 Elasticity and Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115
5.4 Elasticity in Areas Other Than Price . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123
Chapter 6: Consumer Choices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 133
6.1 Consumption Choices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134
6.2 How Changes in Income and Prices Affect Consumption Choices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141
6.3 Behavioral Economics: An Alternative Framework for Consumer Choice . . . . . . . . . . . 147
Chapter 7: Production, Costs, and Industry Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155
7.1 Explicit and Implicit Costs, and Accounting and Economic Profit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 157
7.2 Production in the Short Run . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158
7.3 Costs in the Short Run . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164
7.4 Production in the Long Run . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 171
7.5 Costs in the Long Run . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 172
Chapter 8: Perfect Competition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 187
8.1 Perfect Competition and Why It Matters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 188
8.2 How Perfectly Competitive Firms Make Output Decisions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 189
8.3 Entry and Exit Decisions in the Long Run . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 204
8.4 Efficiency in Perfectly Competitive Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 206
Chapter 9: Monopoly . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 215
9.1 How Monopolies Form: Barriers to Entry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 216
9.2 How a Profit-Maximizing Monopoly Chooses Output and Price . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 220
Chapter 10: Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 235
10.1 Monopolistic Competition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 236
10.2 Oligopoly . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 244
Chapter 11: Monopoly and Antitrust Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 255
11.1 Corporate Mergers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 256
11.2 Regulating Anticompetitive Behavior . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 262
11.3 Regulating Natural Monopolies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 264
11.4 The Great Deregulation Experiment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 267
Chapter 12: Environmental Protection and Negative Externalities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 275
12.1 The Economics of Pollution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 276
12.2 Command-and-Control Regulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 280
12.3 Market-Oriented Environmental Tools . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 281
12.4 The Benefits and Costs of U.S. Environmental Laws . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 285
12.5 International Environmental Issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 288
12.6 The Tradeoff between Economic Output and Environmental Protection . . . . . . . . . . . 289
Chapter 13: Positive Externalities and Public Goods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 301
13.1 Why the Private Sector Underinvests in Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 303
13.2 How Governments Can Encourage Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 306
13.3 Public Goods . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 309
Chapter 14: Labor Markets and Income . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 319
14.1 The Theory of Labor Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 320
14.2 Wages and Employment in an Imperfectly Competitive Labor Market . . . . . . . . . . . . 326
14.3 Market Power on the Supply Side of Labor Markets: Unions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 330
14.4 Bilateral Monopoly . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 337
14.5 Employment Discrimination . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 338
14.6 Immigration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 343
Chapter 15: Poverty and Economic Inequality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 353
15.1 Drawing the Poverty Line . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 354
15.2 The Poverty Trap . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 357
15.3 The Safety Net . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 360
15.4 Income Inequality: Measurement and Causes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 364
15.5 Government Policies to Reduce Income Inequality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 370
Chapter 16: Information, Risk, and Insurance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 381
16.1 The Problem of Imperfect Information and Asymmetric Information . . . . . . . . . . . . . 382
16.2 Insurance and Imperfect Information . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 388
Chapter 17: Financial Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 401
17.1 How Businesses Raise Financial Capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 403
17.2 How Households Supply Financial Capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 406
17.3 How to Accumulate Personal Wealth . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 418
Chapter 18: Public Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 429
18.1 Voter Participation and Costs of Elections . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 430
18.2 Special Interest Politics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 432
18.3 Flaws in the Democratic System of Government . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 435
Chapter 19: International Trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 443
19.1 Absolute and Comparative Advantage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 444
19.2 What Happens When a Country Has an Absolute Advantage in All Goods . . . . . . . . . 450
19.3 Intra-industry Trade between Similar Economies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 454
19.4 The Benefits of Reducing Barriers to International Trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 458
Chapter 20: Globalization and Protectionism . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 465
20.1 Protectionism: An Indirect Subsidy from Consumers to Producers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 466
20.2 International Trade and Its Effects on Jobs, Wages, and Working Conditions . . . . . . . . 473
20.3 Arguments in Support of Restricting Imports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 476
20.4 How Governments Enact Trade Policy: Globally, Regionally, and Nationally . . . . . . . . 481
20.5 The Tradeoffs of Trade Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 485
A | The Use of Mathematics in Principles of Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 493
B | Indifference Curves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 509
C | Present Discounted Value . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 523
Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 569
This OpenStax book is available for free at http://cnx.org/content/col12170/1.7
PREFACE
Welcome to Principles of Microeconomics 2e (2nd Edition), an OpenStax resource. This textbook was written to
increase student access to high-quality learning materials, maintaining highest standards of academic rigor at little to
no cost.
About OpenStax
OpenStax is a nonprofit based at Rice University, and it’s our mission to improve student access to education. Our first
openly licensed college textbook was published in 2012, and our library has since scaled to over 25 books for college
and AP® courses used by hundreds of thousands of students. OpenStax Tutor, our low-cost personalized learning tool,
is being used in college courses throughout the country. Through our partnerships with philanthropic foundations and
our alliance with other educational resource organizations, OpenStax is breaking down the most common barriers to
learning and empowering students and instructors to succeed.
About OpenStax resources
Customization
Principles of Microeconomics 2e is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International (CC BY)
license, which means that you can distribute, remix, and build upon the content, as long as you provide attribution to
OpenStax and its content contributors.
Because our books are openly licensed, you are free to use the entire book or pick and choose the sections that are
most relevant to the needs of your course. Feel free to remix the content by assigning your students certain chapters
and sections in your syllabus, in the order that you prefer. You can even provide a direct link in your syllabus to the
sections in the web view of your book.
Instructors also have the option of creating a customized version of their OpenStax book. The custom version can
be made available to students in low-cost print or digital form through their campus bookstore. Visit the Instructor
Resources section of your book page on OpenStax.org for more information.
Errata
All OpenStax textbooks undergo a rigorous review process. However, like any professional-grade textbook, errors
sometimes occur. Since our books are web based, we can make updates periodically when deemed pedagogically
necessary. If you have a correction to suggest, submit it through the link on your book page on OpenStax.org. Subject
matter experts review all errata suggestions. OpenStax is committed to remaining transparent about all updates, so
you will also find a list of past errata changes on your book page on OpenStax.org.
Format
You can access this textbook for free in web view or PDF through OpenStax.org, and for a low cost in print.
About Principles of Microeconomics 2e
Principles of Microeconomics 2e (2nd edition) covers the scope and sequence of most introductory microeconomics
courses. The text includes many current examples, which are handled in a politically equitable way. The outcome is
a balanced approach to the theory and application of economics concepts. The second edition has been thoroughly
revised to increase clarity, update data and current event impacts, and incorporate the feedback from many reviewers
and adopters.
Coverage and scope
To develop the first edition of Principles of Microeconomics, we acquired the rights to Timothy Taylor’s Principles of
Economics and solicited ideas from economics instructors at all levels of higher education, from community colleges
to PhD-granting universities. For the second edition, we received even more expansive and actionable feedback from
hundreds of adopters who had used the book for several academic terms. These knowledgeable instructors informed
the pedagogical courses, learning objective development and fulfillment, and the chapter arrangements. Faculty who
taught from the material provided critical and detailed commentary.
Preface 1
The result is a book that covers the breadth of economics topics and also provides the necessary depth to ensure the
course is manageable for instructors and students alike. We strove to balance theory and application, as well as the
amount of calculation and mathematical examples.
The book is organized into five main parts:
What is Economics? The first two chapters introduce students to the study of economics with a focus on
making choices in a world of scarce resources.
Supply and Demand, Chapters 3 and 4, introduces and explains the first analytical model in
economics–supply, demand, and equilibrium–before showing applications in the markets for labor and
finance.
The Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory, Chapters 5 through 10, begins the microeconomics portion
of the text, presenting the theories of consumer behavior, production and costs, and the different models of
market structure, including some simple game theory.
Microeconomic Policy Issues, Chapters 11 through 18, covers the range of topics in applied micro, framed
around the concepts of public goods and positive and negative externalities. Students explore competition and
antitrust policies, environmental problems, poverty, income inequality, and other labor market issues. The text
also covers information, risk and financial markets, and public economy.
International Economics, Chapters 19 and 20, introduces the international dimensions of economics,
including international trade and protectionism.
Alternate sequencing
Principles of Microeconomics 2e was conceived and written to fit a particular topical sequence, but it can be used
flexibly to accommodate other course structures. One such potential structure, which fits reasonably well with
the textbook content, is provided. Please consider, however, that the chapters were not written to be completely
independent, and that the proposed alternate sequence should be carefully considered for student preparation and
textual consistency.
Chapter 1 Welcome to Economics!
Chapter 2 Choice in a World of Scarcity
Chapter 3 Demand and Supply
Chapter 4 Labor and Financial Markets
Chapter 5 Elasticity
Chapter 6 Consumer Choices
Chapter 19 International Trade
Chapter 7 Cost and Industry Structure
Chapter 12 Environmental Protection and Negative Externalities
Chapter 13 Positive Externalities and Public Goods
Chapter 8 Perfect Competition
Chapter 9 Monopoly
Chapter 10 Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly
Chapter 11 Monopoly and Antitrust Policy
Chapter 14 Labor Markets and Income
Chapter 15 Poverty and Economic Inequality
Chapter 16 Information, Risk, and Insurance
Chapter 17 Financial Markets
Chapter 18 Public Economy
Chapter 20 Globalization and Protectionism
Appendix A The Use of Mathematics in Principles of Economics
Appendix B Indifference Curves
Appendix C Present Discounted Value
Changes to the second edition
OpenStax only undertakes revisions when significant modifications to a text are necessary. In the case of Principles
of Microeconomics, we received a wealth of constructive feedback. Many of the book’s users felt that consequential
2 Preface
This OpenStax book is available for free at http://cnx.org/content/col12170/1.7
movement in economic data, coupled with the impacts of national and global events, warranted a full revision. We
also took advantage of the opportunity to improve the writing and sequencing of the text, as well as many of the
calculation examples. The major changes are summarized below.
Augmented explanations in chapters one through four provide a more comprehensive and informative
foundation for the book.
A clearer explanation, using a numerical example, has been given for finding the utility maximizing
combination of goods and services a consumer should choose.
The labor markets chapter and the poverty and economic inequality chapter have been resequenced.
Substantial revisions to the AD/AS model in chapters 24-26 present the core concepts of macroeconomics in
a clearer, more dynamic manner.
Case studies and examples have been revised and, in some cases, replaced to provide more relevant and useful
information for students.
Economic data, tables, and graphs, as well as discussion and analysis around that data, have been thoroughly
updated.
Wherever possible, data from the Federal Reserve Economic Database (FRED) was included and referenced. In most
of these uses, links to the direct source of the FRED data are provided, and students are encouraged to explore the
information and the overall FRED resources more thoroughly.
Additional updates and revisions appear throughout the book. They reflect changes to economic realities and policies
regarding international trade, taxation, insurance, and other topics. For issues that may change in the months or years
following the textbook's publication, the authors often provided a more open-ended explanation, but we will update
the text annually to address further changes.
The revision of Principles of Microeconomics was undertaken by Steven Greenlaw (University of Mary Washington)
and David Shapiro (Pennsylvania State University), with significant input by lead reviewer Daniel MacDonald
(California State University, San Bernardino).
Pedagogical foundation
Throughout Principles of Microeconomics 2e, you will find features that engage the students in economic inquiry and
support their learning. Our features include:
Bring It Home. This feature presents a brief case study, specific to each chapter, which connects the chapter’s
main topic to the real world. It is broken up into two parts: the first at the beginning of the chapter (in the Intro
module) and the second at chapter’s end, when students have learned what’s necessary to understand the case
and “bring home” the chapter’s core concepts.
Work It Out. This feature asks students to work through a generally analytical or computational problem, and
guides them step-by-step to find out …
CATEGORIES
Economics
Nursing
Applied Sciences
Psychology
Science
Management
Computer Science
Human Resource Management
Accounting
Information Systems
English
Anatomy
Operations Management
Sociology
Literature
Education
Business & Finance
Marketing
Engineering
Statistics
Biology
Political Science
Reading
History
Financial markets
Philosophy
Mathematics
Law
Criminal
Architecture and Design
Government
Social Science
World history
Chemistry
Humanities
Business Finance
Writing
Programming
Telecommunications Engineering
Geography
Physics
Spanish
ach
e. Embedded Entrepreneurship
f. Three Social Entrepreneurship Models
g. Social-Founder Identity
h. Micros-enterprise Development
Outcomes
Subset 2. Indigenous Entrepreneurship Approaches (Outside of Canada)
a. Indigenous Australian Entrepreneurs Exami
Calculus
(people influence of
others) processes that you perceived occurs in this specific Institution Select one of the forms of stratification highlighted (focus on inter the intersectionalities
of these three) to reflect and analyze the potential ways these (
American history
Pharmacology
Ancient history
. Also
Numerical analysis
Environmental science
Electrical Engineering
Precalculus
Physiology
Civil Engineering
Electronic Engineering
ness Horizons
Algebra
Geology
Physical chemistry
nt
When considering both O
lassrooms
Civil
Probability
ions
Identify a specific consumer product that you or your family have used for quite some time. This might be a branded smartphone (if you have used several versions over the years)
or the court to consider in its deliberations. Locard’s exchange principle argues that during the commission of a crime
Chemical Engineering
Ecology
aragraphs (meaning 25 sentences or more). Your assignment may be more than 5 paragraphs but not less.
INSTRUCTIONS:
To access the FNU Online Library for journals and articles you can go the FNU library link here:
https://www.fnu.edu/library/
In order to
n that draws upon the theoretical reading to explain and contextualize the design choices. Be sure to directly quote or paraphrase the reading
ce to the vaccine. Your campaign must educate and inform the audience on the benefits but also create for safe and open dialogue. A key metric of your campaign will be the direct increase in numbers.
Key outcomes: The approach that you take must be clear
Mechanical Engineering
Organic chemistry
Geometry
nment
Topic
You will need to pick one topic for your project (5 pts)
Literature search
You will need to perform a literature search for your topic
Geophysics
you been involved with a company doing a redesign of business processes
Communication on Customer Relations. Discuss how two-way communication on social media channels impacts businesses both positively and negatively. Provide any personal examples from your experience
od pressure and hypertension via a community-wide intervention that targets the problem across the lifespan (i.e. includes all ages).
Develop a community-wide intervention to reduce elevated blood pressure and hypertension in the State of Alabama that in
in body of the report
Conclusions
References (8 References Minimum)
*** Words count = 2000 words.
*** In-Text Citations and References using Harvard style.
*** In Task section I’ve chose (Economic issues in overseas contracting)"
Electromagnetism
w or quality improvement; it was just all part of good nursing care. The goal for quality improvement is to monitor patient outcomes using statistics for comparison to standards of care for different diseases
e a 1 to 2 slide Microsoft PowerPoint presentation on the different models of case management. Include speaker notes... .....Describe three different models of case management.
visual representations of information. They can include numbers
SSAY
ame workbook for all 3 milestones. You do not need to download a new copy for Milestones 2 or 3. When you submit Milestone 3
pages):
Provide a description of an existing intervention in Canada
making the appropriate buying decisions in an ethical and professional manner.
Topic: Purchasing and Technology
You read about blockchain ledger technology. Now do some additional research out on the Internet and share your URL with the rest of the class
be aware of which features their competitors are opting to include so the product development teams can design similar or enhanced features to attract more of the market. The more unique
low (The Top Health Industry Trends to Watch in 2015) to assist you with this discussion.
https://youtu.be/fRym_jyuBc0
Next year the $2.8 trillion U.S. healthcare industry will finally begin to look and feel more like the rest of the business wo
evidence-based primary care curriculum. Throughout your nurse practitioner program
Vignette
Understanding Gender Fluidity
Providing Inclusive Quality Care
Affirming Clinical Encounters
Conclusion
References
Nurse Practitioner Knowledge
Mechanics
and word limit is unit as a guide only.
The assessment may be re-attempted on two further occasions (maximum three attempts in total). All assessments must be resubmitted 3 days within receiving your unsatisfactory grade. You must clearly indicate “Re-su
Trigonometry
Article writing
Other
5. June 29
After the components sending to the manufacturing house
1. In 1972 the Furman v. Georgia case resulted in a decision that would put action into motion. Furman was originally sentenced to death because of a murder he committed in Georgia but the court debated whether or not this was a violation of his 8th amend
One of the first conflicts that would need to be investigated would be whether the human service professional followed the responsibility to client ethical standard. While developing a relationship with client it is important to clarify that if danger or
Ethical behavior is a critical topic in the workplace because the impact of it can make or break a business
No matter which type of health care organization
With a direct sale
During the pandemic
Computers are being used to monitor the spread of outbreaks in different areas of the world and with this record
3. Furman v. Georgia is a U.S Supreme Court case that resolves around the Eighth Amendments ban on cruel and unsual punishment in death penalty cases. The Furman v. Georgia case was based on Furman being convicted of murder in Georgia. Furman was caught i
One major ethical conflict that may arise in my investigation is the Responsibility to Client in both Standard 3 and Standard 4 of the Ethical Standards for Human Service Professionals (2015). Making sure we do not disclose information without consent ev
4. Identify two examples of real world problems that you have observed in your personal
Summary & Evaluation: Reference & 188. Academic Search Ultimate
Ethics
We can mention at least one example of how the violation of ethical standards can be prevented. Many organizations promote ethical self-regulation by creating moral codes to help direct their business activities
*DDB is used for the first three years
For example
The inbound logistics for William Instrument refer to purchase components from various electronic firms. During the purchase process William need to consider the quality and price of the components. In this case
4. A U.S. Supreme Court case known as Furman v. Georgia (1972) is a landmark case that involved Eighth Amendment’s ban of unusual and cruel punishment in death penalty cases (Furman v. Georgia (1972)
With covid coming into place
In my opinion
with
Not necessarily all home buyers are the same! When you choose to work with we buy ugly houses Baltimore & nationwide USA
The ability to view ourselves from an unbiased perspective allows us to critically assess our personal strengths and weaknesses. This is an important step in the process of finding the right resources for our personal learning style. Ego and pride can be
· By Day 1 of this week
While you must form your answers to the questions below from our assigned reading material
CliftonLarsonAllen LLP (2013)
5 The family dynamic is awkward at first since the most outgoing and straight forward person in the family in Linda
Urien
The most important benefit of my statistical analysis would be the accuracy with which I interpret the data. The greatest obstacle
From a similar but larger point of view
4 In order to get the entire family to come back for another session I would suggest coming in on a day the restaurant is not open
When seeking to identify a patient’s health condition
After viewing the you tube videos on prayer
Your paper must be at least two pages in length (not counting the title and reference pages)
The word assimilate is negative to me. I believe everyone should learn about a country that they are going to live in. It doesnt mean that they have to believe that everything in America is better than where they came from. It means that they care enough
Data collection
Single Subject Chris is a social worker in a geriatric case management program located in a midsize Northeastern town. She has an MSW and is part of a team of case managers that likes to continuously improve on its practice. The team is currently using an
I would start off with Linda on repeating her options for the child and going over what she is feeling with each option. I would want to find out what she is afraid of. I would avoid asking her any “why” questions because I want her to be in the here an
Summarize the advantages and disadvantages of using an Internet site as means of collecting data for psychological research (Comp 2.1) 25.0\% Summarization of the advantages and disadvantages of using an Internet site as means of collecting data for psych
Identify the type of research used in a chosen study
Compose a 1
Optics
effect relationship becomes more difficult—as the researcher cannot enact total control of another person even in an experimental environment. Social workers serve clients in highly complex real-world environments. Clients often implement recommended inte
I think knowing more about you will allow you to be able to choose the right resources
Be 4 pages in length
soft MB-920 dumps review and documentation and high-quality listing pdf MB-920 braindumps also recommended and approved by Microsoft experts. The practical test
g
One thing you will need to do in college is learn how to find and use references. References support your ideas. College-level work must be supported by research. You are expected to do that for this paper. You will research
Elaborate on any potential confounds or ethical concerns while participating in the psychological study 20.0\% Elaboration on any potential confounds or ethical concerns while participating in the psychological study is missing. Elaboration on any potenti
3 The first thing I would do in the family’s first session is develop a genogram of the family to get an idea of all the individuals who play a major role in Linda’s life. After establishing where each member is in relation to the family
A Health in All Policies approach
Note: The requirements outlined below correspond to the grading criteria in the scoring guide. At a minimum
Chen
Read Connecting Communities and Complexity: A Case Study in Creating the Conditions for Transformational Change
Read Reflections on Cultural Humility
Read A Basic Guide to ABCD Community Organizing
Use the bolded black section and sub-section titles below to organize your paper. For each section
Losinski forwarded the article on a priority basis to Mary Scott
Losinksi wanted details on use of the ED at CGH. He asked the administrative resident